Contract Duration and the Costs of Market Transactions
Alexander MacKay
Harvard University
May 11, 2020
Abstract
The optimal duration of a supply contract balances the costs of re-selecting a supplier
against the costs of being matched to an inefficient supplier when the contract lasts too
long. I develop a structural model of contract duration that captures this tradeoff and
provide an empirical strategy for quantifying (unobserved) transaction costs. I estimate
the model using federal supply contracts for a standardized product, where suppliers are
selected by procurement auctions. The estimated transaction costs are substantially greater
than consumer switching costs and a significant portion of total buyer costs. Counterfactuals
illustrate the importance of accounting for the duration margin.
JEL Codes: D22, D44, H57, L13, L14
Keywords: Supply Contracts, Intermediate Goods, Switching Costs, Auctions
An earlier version of this paper circulated with the title “The Structure of Costs and the Duration of Supply
Relationships.” This version reflects an expanded data collection effort and a larger dataset. I am especially grateful
for the helpful comments and suggestions of Ali Hortaçsu, Brent Hickman, Casey Mulligan, Chad Syverson, and
Stephane Bonhomme. This paper has benefited from conversations with Ramon Casadesus-Masanell, Scott Komin-
ers, Maciej Kotowski, Steve Tadelis, Paola Valbonesi, Dennis Yao, and my Ph.D. classmates at the University of
Chicago, among others. I also thank seminar and conference participants at the University of Chicago, the CEPR-JIE
Conference, the Econometric Society World Congress, Northwestern (Kellogg), Harvard Business School, Carnegie
Mellon, UCLA (Anderson), Rice, the International Industrial Organization Conference, Rochester (Simon), and the
Berkeley-Paris Organizational Economics Workshop.
Harvard University, Harvard Business School. Email: [email protected].
1 Introduction
When buyers select sellers, they select not only who but also how long. For the supply of
services, the duration of a buyer-seller relationship is often formalized in a contract. At the
expiration of the contract, the buyer returns to the market to re-select a supplier. The buyer
bears some costs for doing so: each time the buyer goes to market, he must identify potential
sellers, negotiate, determine the new seller, and draw up a contract (Coase, 1937, 1960). These
market transaction costs all occur before an agreement is reached.
1
As noted by Coase (1937),
a key motivation for a longer contract is to avoid these costs. Choosing a two-year contract
instead of sequential one-year contracts can cut these ex ante costs in half.
Though going to the market frequently can be costly, there are typically gains from doing so.
Consider a procurement auction that selects the efficient (lowest-cost) supplier. Over a longer
contract, the lowest-cost supplier at the beginning of the contract may not have the lowest cost
by the end. By running more frequent auctions with shorter contracts, the buyer can switch
among the lowest-cost suppliers and pay a lower price. In the absence of transaction costs, the
buyer would prefer a spot market that allocates the lowest-cost supplier in every instant.
In the exchange of intermediate goods, market transactions can be especially costly. Un-
like the retail sector, markets for intermediate goods are typically not well established. When
running a procurement auction, a buyer brings together potential sellers and administers a
mechanism to determine the winner and the price. In a sense, the buyer bears the cost of
creating his market. Each transaction typically requires market research, advertising the op-
portunity, and additional steps to ensure that the process complies with the buyer’s internal
policies. Even for standardized goods and services (e.g., raw materials, electricity, paper prod-
ucts, and accounting services), market transaction costs can be large, as exact specifications
vary among buyers. Indeed, as inputs, these products are typically sold on fixed-price, fixed-
duration contracts, rather than in spot markets.
2
Thus, we may infer that market transaction
costs are meaningful for a wide variety of goods and services.
Despite their importance, quantifying transaction costs has proven challenging, as they are
typically unobserved. To address this, I develop an empirical model where a buyer selects a
seller from an imperfectly competitive market. The buyer chooses the duration of the contract
to balance ex ante transaction costs against the benefit from selecting more efficient suppliers.
This tradeoff is intuitive and corresponds to a common real-world contracting problem. The
model also provides a novel strategy for the direct estimation of transaction costs. By revealed
1
Market transaction costs correspond to the first two categories of the taxonomy of transaction costs suggested
by Dahlman (1979): (1) search and information costs and (2) bargaining and decision costs. The third category, (3)
policing and enforcement costs, relates to the principal-agent problem and incomplete contracts, which have been
the focus of the literature on transaction costs following Williamson (1979).
2
In their seminal NBER survey, Stigler and Kindahl (1970) found that about half of the commodities in their
sample were purchased with fixed-term contracts. A more recent comprehensive survey has not been conducted
and would be welcome. Fixed-price contracts constitute over 90 percent of U.S. federal government contracts
(source: Federal Procurement Data System), and, anecdotally, remain predominant in the private sector.
1
preference, transaction costs may be identified from the duration of the contract and the price
schedule faced by the buyer. I apply the model in the context of federal procurement for
a standardized product, and I find that market transaction costs are large and economically
meaningful, comprising 10.9 percent of total buyer costs. Thus, I provide the first estimates of
transaction costs in intermediate goods markets.
3
The estimates suggest that transaction costs can be quite large. Though a detailed analysis
of what comprises these costs is limited by the available data, a rough breakdown indicates
that several components may be meaningful sources of ex ante transaction costs, including
formal due diligence procedures and the direct costs of the bidding mechanism. Further work
is needed to better understand these costs and their impacts in various settings.
The model of optimal contract duration and its main implications are presented in Section
2. One novel prediction of the model is that, in equilibrium, a longer contract would result in a
higher price. This arises from straightforward economic logic: if a longer duration would reduce
the price, the buyer would prefer it, because it would also reduce the burden of transaction
costs.
4
A price schedule that is increasing with duration is the natural result of time-varying
supply costs among suppliers, and it may arise from, e.g., capacity constraints or idiosyncratic
outside options. Therefore, the model provides an economic justification for shorter contracts.
I focus on a setting in which goods and services are standardized, there is little uncertainty,
and relationship-specific investments are negligible. Even in these straightforward economic
environments, the duration decision is non-trivial, depending on (1) the magnitude of the
transaction costs, (2) the degree of competition, and (3) the stochastic properties of the under-
lying supply costs. I present a simplified version of the model to provide some intuition about
these features. Perhaps surprisingly, the optimal duration is non-monotonic in the degree of
competition. With few suppliers, the benefit of re-selecting a supplier is small, and long-term
contracts are optimal. This benefit increases as the number of suppliers increases, leading to
short-term contracts at moderate levels of competition. With many suppliers, the buyer can
find a seller that provides a low-enough price over many periods, so long-term contracts are
once again optimal. Likewise, higher variance in supply costs could lead to longer or shorter
contracts. These ambiguous predictions help motivate a structural approach to estimation.
For an empirical application, I select a specialized setting that allows me to isolate the trade-
off described above and recover estimates of market transaction costs. I construct a unique
dataset of 1,046 contracts for building cleaning services for the U.S. federal government. Con-
sistent with the model, duration is determined ex ante by the local government agency, and, for
3
Economists studying the effects of transaction costs have primarily pursued the testable implications of these
costs, rather than their direct estimation (see, e.g., Monteverde and Teece, 1982; Walker and Weber, 1984). One
recent exception is Atalay et al. (2017), who construct a measurement of external transaction costs by examining
input flows between integrated and non-integrated firms across sectors. Likewise, the literature on contract duration
has also focused on testable implications rather than structural modeling.
4
By contrast, the prevailing wisdom in the transaction costs literature is that longer contracts tend to reduce
supply costs by solving ex post incentive problems.
2
the contracts I analyze, the government is required to go to market at the expiration of the pre-
vious contract. Importantly, building cleaning services are standardized, supply-side conditions
are stable, and relationship-specific investments are small.
5
This suggests that abstracting away
from other contracting concerns may be reasonable, and it allows me to focus on identifying
the direct (Coasian) costs of going to the market.
For context, each year the federal government manages over one million contracts that have
an annual value of less than $1 million. These constitute 97 percent of all federal contracts
and are disproportionally made with fixed-price, fixed-duration contracts through competitive
procedures.
6
In prices, the estimation sample is roughly comparable to these contracts and
closely resembles the full set of building cleaning contracts. The data are presented in Section
3, along with descriptive regressions that are used to motivate the structural model. I verify a
core prediction of the model: in the data, longer contracts are more expensive. Therefore, time-
varying supply costs appear to outweigh potential supplier-side benefits from a longer contract
(e.g., learning), which are likely small in this setting.
Section 4 presents the specific modeling assumptions and parameterizations used to take
the model to data. Consistent with the empirical setting, the model takes three stages: (1)
the buyer’s duration decision, (2) a participation decision by suppliers, and (3) a first-price
auction. Thus, compared to a standard auction model with endogenous entry, the model also
incorporates a strategic decision by the buyer (duration). As in Krasnokutskaya (2011), I allow
for unobserved heterogeneity across auctions. I show that the joint distribution of private costs
and unobserved heterogeneity are identified when only the winning bid and the number of
bidders are observed, thus extending identification to data that are more broadly available.
7
Intuitively, variation in the number of bids shifts the distribution of the private component in a
known way, while the distribution of auction-specific heterogeneity is unaffected.
Section 5 presents the model estimates. The median estimated transaction cost is $10,400,
representing a meaningful portion of total buyer costs. Though providing a detailed breakdown
of these costs lies beyond the scope of the paper—in part due to the fact that they are not di-
rectly observed—I provide some discussion of what comprises these costs using supplementary
data. In magnitude, the estimates are roughly comparable to back-of-the-envelope calculations
of the labor costs of procurement specialists. Further, I find that these costs are correlated with
5
Ex post incentive problems, which are a large focus of the contract literature, are not a first-order concern here.
Contracts have detailed specifications, performance is observable, and contracts are rarely canceled. I discuss this
further in Section 3.2. Hyytinen et al. (2018), who study cleaning contracts in Sweden, make similar observations
and also assume complete contracts. As is common in the auction literature, Hyytinen et al. (2018) do not analyze
the duration margin.
6
Source: Federal Procurement Data System.
7
Previous approaches relied on observing either multiple bids per auction (Krasnokutskaya, 2011; Hu et al.,
2013) or a reservation price (Roberts, 2013). Aradillas-López et al. (2013) exploit variation in the number bids for
second-price auctions, though the identification results of their paper are limited to constructing bounds on surplus.
Concurrent work by Quint (2015) exploits variation in the number of bidders in a model with additively separa-
ble unobserved heterogeneity. That identification strategy does not translate to the more common multiplicative
structure examined here.
3
other observables in ways that align with our intuition. For example, the costs are positively
correlated with the complexity of the facility: contracts for medical buildings have much higher
transaction costs than those for offices.
In Section 6, I provide two counterfactual exercises to illustrate the impact of the dura-
tion margin, which is generally not accounted for in empirical studies of procurement or other
business-to-business settings. First, I consider the value to the buyer of the strategic ability
to change the duration of the contract. Instead of optimizing for each contract, I consider an
alternative policy where all contracts are issued with a standard duration. Mandating more fre-
quent transactions could be costly. For instance, issuing only one-year contracts would increase
total costs by 37 percent. Of standard contracts with full-year durations, the four-year standard
term has the lowest impact, increasing total costs by 1.4 percent. Therefore, a poorly chosen
standard could substantially increase costs, but an informed standard may have modest effects.
As a second counterfactual, I demonstrate the impact of endogenous contracts on the esti-
mation of welfare effects. To illustrate the importance of this margin, I consider the effects on
cost pass-through. When buyers can adjust duration, the pass-through of supply costs to prices
is reduced by 10 percent, compared to a world in which duration is held fixed. Thus, appropri-
ately modeling contract duration can change the interpretation of observed price changes and
the estimation of welfare effects. Further, transaction costs may be a sizable portion of total
costs and should be accounted for in addition to any price effects.
8
A novel contribution of this paper is an empirical model of optimal contract duration. To
the best of my knowledge, this is the first model to illustrate a general cost of longer contracts,
which arises from suboptimal buyer-seller matching over time. The previous literature on con-
tract duration has focused on ex post coordination problems, primarily through costly rene-
gotiation (Masten and Crocker, 1985) and relationship-specific investments (Joskow, 1987).
Recent empirical work on these features (e.g., Decarolis, 2014; Bajari et al., 2014) focuses on
one-time projects and therefore does not model repeated demand. As discussed above, I ab-
stract away from such ex post incentive problems and focus on “recurrent spot contracting,”
in the terminology of Williamson (1979). For commodities and simple products, finding the
lowest-cost supplier is often more important than whether buyer and seller incentives are prop-
erly aligned. I am also able to test for and abstract away from incumbency advantage, which
is often a concern in settings with repeated contracts (see, e.g., Greenstein, 1993). My work is
complementary to models with these features.
9
8
Carlton and Keating (2015) emphasize the role of transaction costs in welfare analysis when the affected vari-
able is not simply the price level, through the effect on a firm’s ability to implement nonlinear pricing.
9
The tradeoff in this paper between transaction costs and price is closely related to the models of contract
duration of Dye (1985) and Gray (1978), who take the stochastic price process as given. An innovation of this
paper is to use tools of industrial organization to model primitives of the price process and explore its implications.
The contract duration decision is also theoretically linked to a simultaneous bundling problem, where the contract
bundles demand over time. In the bundling literature, Zhou (2017) and Palfrey (1983) provide the most closely
related analogues. Compared to Zhou (2017) and Palfrey (1983), I allow for intermediate degrees of bundling and
introduce transaction costs. I demonstrate that the smaller variance induced by bundling reduces total surplus when
4
A related empirical literature measures switching costs in consumer markets (e.g., Dubé
et al., 2010; Handel, 2013; Honka, 2014; Luco, 2019). These studies also use a revealed-
preference approach to recover switching costs, using a different identification strategy that
is made possible by the economic environment. Conceptually, switching costs in consumer
markets can be inferred from posted prices,
10
whereas contract prices for intermediate goods
are idiosyncratic to the buyer-seller match. Additionally, the switching costs literature tends
to take supply costs as exogenous, whereas variation in supply costs is a key factor in the
decision to switch suppliers in my setting. As one might expect, I find that transaction costs in
intermediate goods markets are substantially higher than consumer switching costs.
11
The theoretical and empirical analysis of the costs of market transactions has typically been
cast in light of the decision to vertically integrate (for a summary, see Lafontaine and Slade,
2007). Through integration, buyers and sellers can avoid the costs of going to the market, in
addition to realizing other benefits. Supply contracts provide an intermediate option, lying be-
tween arms-length transactions and vertical integration. As noted by Coase (1960), conditions
that favor longer contracts are also likely to favor vertical integration. Thus, the mechanisms
studied in this paper may also be relevant for the analysis of vertical integration.
2 Model
Consider a buyer that demands a good or service for many periods. In the model I introduce, the
buyer chooses the duration of the contract, balancing the per-period payment to suppliers with
the market transaction costs realized at the beginning of each contract. I provide a numerical
example to illustrate this key tradeoff. A central empirical implication of the model is that it
may be applied to recover unobserved transaction costs. The model does not capture every
real-world consideration, but its representation of a key contracting tradeoff provides the basis
for an empirical investigation into the magnitudes of transaction costs.
2.1 The Buyer’s Problem
A risk-neutral buyer has inelastic demand for a good or service over many (infinite) future
periods. The buyer selects a single seller and can commit to buy from that seller for multiple
periods with a contract. The buyer announces the duration of the contract (T ) in advance of
there are no transaction costs. Relatedly, Salinger (1995), Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999), Cantillon and Pesendorfer
(2006) note that bundling affects prices by reducing the variance of average valuations.
10
See, for example, Dubé et al. (2010) for orange juice and margarine or Elzinga and Mills (1998) for wholesale
cigarettes. The wholesale market in the analysis of Elzinga and Mills (1998) mirrors a consumer market in that
pricing, though nonlinear, is uniformly applied.
11
A key feature of consumer markets is an inability to contract on future prices, leading to models that weigh an
“investing” effect versus a “harvesting” effect (Klemperer, 1995; Rhodes, 2014; Cabral, 2016). When buyers and
sellers agree on future prices, as in this paper, these effects are competed away.
5
implementing a market mechanism, which is used to select the seller and determine price. Each
time the buyer uses the mechanism, it costs the buyer δ.
The game proceeds in three stages. First, the buyer determines duration T after observing
characteristics of the service x, market conditions m, and the mechanism cost. Second, N
suppliers decide to participate in the market mechanism after observing (T, x, m). Contract
characteristics (T, x) affect the per-period supply costs, while market conditions affect entry
costs (through outside options). Third, a supplier is selected with a per-period stochastic price
P (N, T, x, m), where the price distribution may depend on the duration of the contract and the
number of sellers.
Let P denote the ex ante expected price conditional on (T, x, m), so that P (T, x, m) =
P
N
n=1
(E[P (n, T, x, m)] · Pr(N = n|T, x, m)). The buyer expects market conditions and mech-
anism costs to remain the same in future periods. With this assumption, we use P (T ) in the
exposition below as shorthand, suppressing (x, m).
The value function for the buyer in period τ who has not yet chosen a seller can be expressed
as
V (τ) = min
T
δ +
T
X
k=1
β
k1
P (T) + β
T
V (τ + T ). (1)
After incurring the cost to determine the seller and the price (δ), the buyer pays P(T ) for T
periods and returns to the decision problem in period τ +T . The buyer discounts future periods
at rate β.
For an optimal T , it must be that, for any other duration S:
δ +
T
X
l=1
β
T 1
P (T) + β
T
V (τ + T ) δ +
S
X
l=1
β
S1
P (S) + β
S
V (τ + S). (2)
We can expand each side of the equation by iterating forward to period τ + T · S. As the buyer
expects market conditions to persist, the problem is stationary. If T is optimal in period τ, the
buyer expects T to be optimal at the expiration of a contract in a future period, e.g., in period
τ + T . Plugging in a sequence of contracts of duration T and S, we obtain
S
X
l=1
β
T (l1)
δ +
T
X
k=1
β
k1
P (T)
!
+ β
T ·S
V (τ + T · S) (3)
T
X
l=1
β
S(l1)
δ +
S
X
k=1
β
k1
P (S)
!
+ β
T ·S
V (τ + T · S).
That is, the buyer may pay a per-period price of P (T) while running the market mechanism S
times in S · T periods, or a per-period price of P (S) while running the mechanism T times over
the same horizon.
6
Rearranging,
12
we obtain the optimality condition
P (T) P (S)
δ
P
S
k=1
β
k1
δ
P
T
k=1
β
k1
. (4)
This formulation has straightforward interpretation. The left-hand side is the per-period savings
by choosing contract S instead of T . The right-hand side is the increase in amortized transaction
costs from choosing S instead of T . Thus, at the optimal contract, potential savings in the per-
period price by selecting a different (shorter) duration are less than increased transaction costs
from using the market mechanism more frequently.
Given realizations for contract and market characteristics x and m, the optimal duration,
T
, is therefore given by
T
= arg min
T T
P (T, x, m) +
δ
P
T
k=1
β
k1
, (5)
where T is the set of allowable durations. Intuitively, this expression shows that the buyer’s
objective is to minimize the sum of the per-period supply price and amortized transaction costs.
The optimality condition generates two fundamental results, which we express as our first
propositions:
Proposition 1. If the optimal contract is not the maximum allowable duration (i.e., an interior
solution exits), then the expected per-period price is increasing with the duration of the contract
Proposition 2. If an interior solution exits, then the optimal duration is increasing with transac-
tion costs.
Proof. See Appendix A.
The second proposition is intuitive, and it helps motivate the empirical approach of using
variation in contract duration to recover transaction costs. The first proposition is a direct
result of having ex ante costs for the market mechanism. The buyer can always reduce these
(amortized) costs by choosing a longer contract. Therefore, if the buyer chooses something
other than the maximum duration, it must be that the buyer expects the marginal increase in
the per-period price to offset the decline in transaction costs. As illustrated below, the per-
period price will be increasing when suppliers have idiosyncratic variation in supply costs.
This variation causes the low-cost supplier changes over time and provides a benefit of shorter
contracts.
12
The substitutions δ =
P
T
k=1
β
k1
δ
P
T
k=1
β
k1
on the left-hand side and δ =
P
S
k=1
β
k1
δ
P
S
k=1
β
k1
on the right-
hand side allow us to factor out the common aggregate discount factor
P
T S
k=1
β
k1
=
P
S
l=1
β
T (l1)
P
T
k=1
β
k1
=
P
T
l=1
β
S(l1)
P
S
k=1
β
k1
and simplify.
7
2.2 Illustrative Example
To illustrate the key tradeoff of this model and its implications, consider a stylized example.
Suppose there are N symmetric suppliers in the market, and the set of suppliers stays the same
in every period. The buyer can only issue single-period or two-period contracts. Under these
conditions, the buyer only has to consider the effects of his decision over the next two periods.
Thus, the analysis of the infinite-horizon problem in this example is equivalent to that of a
two-period problem, and I describe it as such for clarity.
Suppliers are risk-neutral and participate in an auction to win the contract. Every supplier
participates in the auction (entry is exogenous). Thus, the mechanism is efficient. The per-
period cost to each supplier is the random variable c. The distribution of c is stable across
periods, but the realizations for each supplier may vary over time. When the buyer issues single-
period contracts, the per-period cost of the winning supplier is c
1:N
, which is the minimum of N
draws of c. When the buyer issues a two-period contract, the average per-period costs for each
supplier is the average of two draws, ˜c =
1
2
(c
(1)
+ c
(2)
), and the cost to the winning supplier is
˜c
1:N
.
This brings us to a key feature about costs in the model:
Remark 1 By changing the duration of the contract, the buyer changes the effective per-period
cost structure faced by suppliers.
As long as the per-period costs c are not perfectly correlated across periods, ˜c 6= c and V ar(˜c) <
V ar(c). As suppliers’ bids will reflect the average cost over the duration of the contract, the
distribution of per-period costs changes with contract duration. When the distribution of supply
costs is stable over time, this serves to reduce the variance of cost draws. The cost of a longer
contract is that the low-cost supplier may not be selected in each period. In the absence of
transaction costs, short-term contracts would be optimal.
Risk-neutrality and symmetry generate the standard auction result that the expected win-
ning bid is equal to the second-order statistic from the cost draws. Thus, the buyer-optimal
contract solves
min{2E[c
2:N
] + 2δ
| {z }
short-term
, 2Ec
2:N
] + δ
| {z }
long-term
} (6)
The buyer will pick the long-term contract if the increase in expected supply costs is less than
the reduction in (amortized) transaction costs, i.e., if
E[˜c
2:N
] E[c
2:N
] <
δ
2
. (7)
This condition mirrors the optimality condition in equation (4).
This simple example illustrates a second key feature of the model:
8
Remark 2 The intensity of supply-side competition, in terms of the number of participating
suppliers, affects the optimal contract by changing the per-period cost structure.
Variation in N affects the left-hand side of (7), changing the marginal effect of a longer contract
on the per-period price. This marginal effect is non-monotonic in N, so an increase in the
number of suppliers has an ambiguous effect on equilibrium contracts. Therefore, the optimal
duration may be decreasing, increasing, or U-shaped with N. I describe the intuition for this
result below along with the numerical example.
To illustrate the above features, I present a numerical example in which the per-period costs
are drawn independently over time from a beta distribution with shape parameters (0.5, 0.5).
Recall that the beta distribution has support [0, 1]. With shape parameters (1, 1) it is equivalent
to a uniform distribution, and as the shape parameters approach zero it approaches a Bernoulli
distribution.
Figure 1 illustrates how expected buyer costs vary with contract duration and the degree
of competition. Panel (a) plots the expected supply price for one-period contracts and a two-
period contract. For N = 3, the expected prices are the same, and for N > 3 the single-period
contracts always have a lower expected price. The blue line in panel (b) plots the difference
between these two lines. This difference is equivalent to the left-hand side of equation 7 and is
non-monotonic in the number of suppliers. The dashed line indicates a transaction cost of 0.20,
which is amortized by two periods. When the blue line falls above this dashed line, the increase
in the expected supply price exceeds the savings in transaction costs, and one-period contracts
are optimal. Panel (c) plots the U-shaped buyer-optimal duration as a function of N. Short-term
contracts are optimal for moderate level of competition; in this case, when N {6, ..., 21}.
This stylized example conveys a general insight from the model. For low levels of com-
petition, the benefit of switching suppliers is low, and long-term contracts are preferred. At
moderate levels of competition, there is an increased benefit of switching among suppliers
more frequently. When competition is intense, the expected costs of both long-term and short-
term contracts approach the lower bound of costs, and therefore long-term contracts, which
minimize transaction costs, are optimal.
Thus, even in a stylized example, the directional predictions of the model are empirical,
depending on particular contract or market conditions. This finding further motivates the use
of a structural approach to assess the impacts of transaction costs. The model also generates
a set of predictions related to the stochastic properties of per-period costs to suppliers. Higher
autocorrelation in supply costs will lead to longer contracts, while higher variance in per-period
supply costs can have effects in either direction. As the remainder of the paper focuses on the
structural approach, I discuss these in more detail in Appendix A.
9
Figure 1: Competition, Costs, and Contract Duration: A Numerical Example
(a) Expected Price of One-Period and Two-Period Contracts
Two−Period Contract
One−Period Contracts
0.00
0.10
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
5 10 15 20 25 30
Number of Suppliers
Expected Price
(b) The Marginal Cost of a Longer Contract
δ
2
= 0.1
0.00
0.05
0.10
5 10 15 20 25 30
Number of Suppliers
Change in Expected Price
(c) The Buyer-Optimal Contract
N=6 N=21
1
2
5 10 15 20 25 30
Number of Suppliers
Optimal Duration
Notes: Panel (a) plots the expected per-period costs for separate one-period contracts and
a bundled two-period contract, as a function of the number of bids. The blue line in panel
(b) is the difference between the two, which is the expected price increase to the buyer.
The dashed line in panel (b) reflects a transaction cost of 0.2 amortized over two periods,
which is the amount saved by issuing a two-period bundled contract. For values of N where
the blue line is above the dashed line (N {6, ..., 21}), short-term contracts are optimal,
as the increase in supply costs from the long-term contract is greater than the savings in
transaction costs. Panel (c) plots the buyer-optimal contract duration.
10
2.3 Identification of Transaction Costs via Revealed Preference
I now discuss the empirical strategy for recovering unobserved transaction costs. The optimality
condition for the buyer generates a contract-specific implied value for δ that rationalizes the
observed duration. Thus, by revealed preference, we can recover δ for each contract.
If a contract T is optimal, then, relative to contract S, we have the following optimality
condition, which is a re-expression of equation (4):
T
X
k=1
β
k1
!
S
X
k=1
β
k1
!
P (T) P (S)
T
X
k=1
β
k1
δ
S
X
k=1
β
k1
δ. (8)
By comparing the optimal contract to one that is one period shorter (S = T 1), we obtain the
inequality
δ
1
β
T 1
T
X
k=1
β
k1
!
T 1
X
k=1
β
k1
!
P (T) P (T 1)
. (9)
Likewise, a comparison of of T to S = T + 1 obtains
δ
1
β
T
T +1
X
k=1
β
k1
!
T
X
k=1
β
k1
!
P (T + 1) P (T )
. (10)
In principle, one could generate an inequality for every element in the duration choice set T,
excluding the chosen contract. The minimum upper bound and the maximum lower bound are
sufficient bounds on δ.
The right-hand sides of the inequalities depend only on the discount rate and the expected
per-period price function. The next result follows immediately:
Proposition 3. When β and P (T) are known, bounds for contract-specific realizations of δ are
identified.
The tightness of the bounds depends on the slope of the function P (T ) and the discount rate
β. Effectively, these parameters are governed by the length of each period. Thus far, we have
used a discrete formulation where 1 unit separates each period. If the length of this unit became
infinitesimally short, then T is chosen from a continuous set and we obtain point identification
of δ. We present this as a corollary:
Corollary 1. When T is continuous (i.e., the duration of each period approaches zero), then δ is
point identified for each contract.
Proof. See Appendix A.
Even in the discrete case, the full distribution of δ can be identified from additional assump-
tions on the relationship between δ and x or m. This distribution can be used as a prior over
the bounds. Recall that P (T ) is shorthand for P(T, x, m).
11
Proposition 4. Assume that there exists a special covariate w that is an element of x or m. This
covariate meets the following two conditions: (i) δ and w are independent and (ii) P (T, x, m)
varies continuously with w. Local variation in w provides local identification of the distribution of
δ. When sufficient variation in P (T, x, m) is generated by variation in w, the distribution of δ is
identified.
Proof. Under the above conditions, the bounds (9) and (10) vary continuously with w. There-
fore, the cumulative distribution function of δ is identified.
The model provides a straightforward way to recover unobserved contract-specific trans-
action costs. A key input to this procedure is the duration-dependent function P (T, x, m).
Intuitively, observed variation in contract duration will be necessary to estimate this function
when not known a priori. I discuss the empirical strategy to estimate this object in Section 4.
2.4 Discussion
Setting
The model captures a setting in which the buyer chooses fixed-price, fixed-duration contracts.
This type of contract is quite common. They constitute the vast majority of government service
contracts, and, anecdotally, are used quite frequently in the private sector. Why might a buyer
choose this type of contract instead of allowing for options to renew or a less formal structure?
Some possible reasons are (a) to maximize the number of suppliers that bid on the next contract
and (b) to protect against favoritism by the buyer’s agent (at the expense of the buyer) through
increased transparency. I take the contract structure as given; an analysis of why fixed-duration
contracts are prevalent lies outside the scope of this paper.
The model abstracts away from ex post transaction costs that arise from the principal-agent
problem and incomplete contracts. These considerations have been studied in detail by the
transaction costs literature. The focus of this paper is on illustrating a new fundamental mech-
anism, which may be important even when ex post transaction costs are negligible or when
complete contracts are possible. In some settings, a richer model that accounts for both ex ante
and ex post transaction costs may be appropriate. Ex post transaction costs tend to suggest
longer contracts, as longer contracts can offer a greater return and better align incentives. By
contrast, the model of this paper illuminates that time-varying supply costs make longer con-
tracts more costly, providing a reason why shorter contracts may be preferred. Even with ex
post transaction costs, the per-period price should be increasing in duration at the equilibrium.
If not, the buyer will opt for a longer contract that reduces the supply price and (both ex ante
and ex post) transaction costs.
One simplifying assumption of the model is that the market transaction costs are fixed. In
some settings, we may expect that these cost vary with the duration of the contract. Longer
12
contracts could require more market research by the buyer or additional costs of drawing up
the contract. This is not a first-order consideration for simple goods and services. The language
of the contracts in the empirical application is not duration-dependent, likely reflecting the
standardized nature of the service and stable market conditions.
Another simplification is that suppliers have perfect foresight about future costs. A more
general setup with imperfect information shares the same qualitative features of this model. For
example, consider the case in which a supplier has no information about future costs. Then the
bid for a longer-duration contract will reflect an average between the current-period realization
and the expected mean of future costs, which is the same across suppliers. Therefore, longer
contracts shrink the variance of prices across suppliers. In this scenario, there is an additional
ex post inefficiency arising from imperfect information, though fixed-price contracts eliminate
this risk to the buyer.
Efficiency
The duration of a fixed-price, fixed-duration contract is typically determined by the buyer. Thus,
the analysis of this paper focuses on buyer-optimal contracts, though the intuition translates to
efficient contracts as well. The buyer is concerned with the supply price, which shares similar
stochastic properties to supply costs in most settings. For example, in the illustrative example
above, expected supply cost and expected price are the first and second order statistics from the
cost distribution, which generate similar directional predictions. In the efficient case, supply-
side frictions such as entry costs should also be incorporated for when analyzing welfare.
Though the qualitative features of the buyer-optimal and the efficient contract are similar,
they are not identical. In Appendix B, I provide an analysis of these two outcomes, as well as
the seller-optimal contract. Contracts that are determined by market participants (buyers and
sellers) may be too long or too short, resulting in wasteful social costs. Counterintuitively, these
extra costs may increase as a market becomes more competitive. Therefore, when ex ante costs
are taken into account, highly competitive markets may be of more concern for regulators than
those that are more concentrated.
13
13
This result occurs because market participants care about price rather than cost, and the price responds more
quickly to a change in contract duration when the number of bidders is large. If we think of expected price as the
expected second-order statistic, and the cost as the first-order statistic, then we have some intuition for why this
could be true. The second-order statistic responds more strongly to a change in variance (or mean) than the first-
order statistic when the number of draws is large and the cost distribution is bounded from below. The buyer (or
seller) internalizes the duration’s effect on the second-order statistic rather than its effect on the first-order statistic.
13
3 Empirical Application: Data and Reduced-Form Analysis
3.1 Data
To estimate the costs of market transactions, I construct a dataset of 1,046 competitive contracts
for building cleaning services for the United States federal government. This market provides
a relatively clean case study to analyze the duration decision and estimate costs. For many
commodity products and services, the buyer (a government agency) is compelled to run a
sealed-bid auction for a contract of a pre-determined duration at the expiration of the previous
contract. Thus, for many federal procurement contracts, the empirical setting is aligned with
the model of the previous section. The sample period is October 2003 to May 2017.
A general empirical challenge is that procured goods and services may have heterogeneity
that is multi-dimensional and difficult to quantify. Thus, I focus on commodity-like goods and
services with standard cost structures. Indeed, products of this sort are numerous in procure-
ment and make up a significant portion of all transactions.
14
From the set of commodity-like
products, building cleaning services were chosen because they are numerous, cost factors are
easily quantified, and there is a lot of variation in contract duration. Finally, demand is inelas-
tic, as there were no significant substitutes. The market for such services is sizable; the federal
government spent $1.2 billion annually on such services. In addition, the standardized nature
of the work, along with the fact that the contracts are rarely terminated, mitigates concerns
about the impact of relationship-specific investments in this setting.
To the best of the author’s knowledge, this is the first dataset on contracts to combine
measures price, duration, and competition, which are the key outcomes of the model. To
construct this dataset, I combined detailed location, price, and vendor information maintained
in the Federal Procurement Data System (FPDS) with contract-specific documents downloaded
from the Federal Business Opportunities (FedBizOpps) website. By law, the FPDS keeps public
records of all contracts for the U.S. federal government, and its data has been used in recent
empirical work (e.g., Kang and Miller, 2017; Bhattacharya, 2018; Decarolis et al., 2018). I was
able to identify 4,119 contracts that appeared in both sources. The final sample was restricted
to competitive contracts in the United States that received more than one bid, had an annual
price of less than $1 million, and included square footage in the text of the contract documents,
which is a key cost factor. These contracts span different types of facilities and government
agencies. For additional details on the construction of the sample, see Appendix C.1.
The FPDS data is subject to measurement error. To correct for this, I collected a subsample
of 75 finalized contracts and cross-validated price, duration, and total contract value to what
was reported in FPDS. The cross-validation approach allowed me to generate accurate measures
14
For context, 97 percent of federal government contracts during the period had an annual price of under $1
million. A counter-example of the ideal setting for this sort of analysis might be a customized, large-scale computer
software system for an agency.
14
for the value of the contract. For details, see Appendix D.
I matched the contract-specific dataset with auxiliary datasets of (1) government contract-
ing expenditures at the same location in related products and (2) local labor market conditions.
Local labor market conditions include county-level unemployment from the Local Area Unem-
ployment Statistics and the number of NAICS-code level establishments in the same 3-digit ZIP
code from the County Business Patterns data.
3.2 Institutional Details
Competitive contracts are posted publicly and allow open competition from registered ven-
dors.
15
Many of these contracts are posted on the centralized web portal FedBizOpps.gov, from
which I collected the data in this analysis. On the website, a prospective supplier can view the
contract details, including contract duration and the square footage of the building, require-
ments for the job, and a list of interested suppliers. From the portal, a supplier submits a bid
to the contracting office that includes the total price over the duration of the contract. The
contracting office determines the winning supplier primarily based on the lowest price. By law,
the contracting office must justify selecting other than the lowest-price offer.
Importantly, contract duration is determined by the local contracting office and varies from
contract to contract, even within an agency. As several industry personnel described to the
author, contract duration is a balance between minimizing the administrative costs of re-
contracting and realizing lower supply costs from re-competing more frequently. Administrative
costs include market research, drafting contract specifications, ensuring compliance with poli-
cies and regulations, advertising the opportunity, administering a supplier selection mechanism,
and concluding the contract. Ex ante transaction costs and the competitive benefits of shorter
contracts are key factors for the duration decision, motivating this market as a case study.
Contracts include specifications for the tasks to be done and their frequencies. For building
cleaning, tasks include mopping, vacuuming carpets, picking up debris, dusting, and emptying
trash cans. For an example list of specifications, see Appendix C.4. Contract documents are
extensive, and multiple documents are often posted for each solicitation. The median primary
document runs 49 pages.
As mentioned previously, one motive for using this market as a case study is that ex post
incentive problems are not a significant concern, based on the nature of the service (Hyytinen
et al., 2018), conversations with contracting officers, and the data. The extensive list of contract
specifications combined with observable performance means these contracts are more or less
complete; ex post incentives might be of more concern in a different equilibrium with less
15
These contracts fall under three categories: Full and Open Competition, Full and Open Competition after the
Exclusion of Sources, and Competed Under Simplified Acquisition. 86 percent of the contracts deemed Full and
Open Competition after the Exclusion of Sources are listed as a small business set-aside. As 96 percent of the
contracts are won by small businesses (as determined by the contracting officer), I ignore this distinction for the
purposes of analysis. See Federal Acquisition Regulation (FAR) Part 5.
15
Table 1: Summary Statistics
Mean Min p25 Median p75 Max
Price (Annual, $) 43,870 1,112 7,259 13,180 26,731 976,538
Contract Value ($) 190,200 2,914 28,500 50,550 102,000 4,882,692
Duration (Years) 4.2 0.4 3.0 5.0 5.0 6.5
Square Footage 25,701 145 3,700 7,000 14,500 2,031,842
Price per Square Foot 2.91 0.16 1.32 2.01 3.14 33.02
Number of Bids 6.5 2.0 4.0 5.0 8.0 40.0
Weekly Frequency 3.5 0.1 2.0 3.0 5.0 7.0
Num. Employees (Winner) 61.5 1.0 3.0 14.0 75.0 650.0
Observations 1046
Notes: The table displays summary statistics for key variables in the contract data. Included are outcomes (price, duration,
and number of bids), as well as cost characteristics such as the number of square feet and the frequency of cleaning. The
last variable is the size of the winning firm, in terms of number of employees.
rich contracts. Service contracts under $1 million annually are rarely canceled, and the use of
fixed-price contracts limits the ability of firms to drive up costs, compared to cost-plus contracts.
In particular, building cleaning services have lower rates of terminations, change orders, and
additional work than the average federal government service contract.
16
For these contracts,
the best estimate of what the buyer pays is the initial stated value of the contract. I provide
empirical support for this in Appendix D.3, where I show that the median overrun, defined as
the difference between the total payments made and the initial value of a contract, is zero.
17
3.3 Summary Statistics
Summary statistics for the contracts are displayed in Table 1. Contracts vary in price, duration,
and the number of bids. As shown later in this section, much of the variation in price can
be captured by the square footage of the building and the weekly cleaning frequency. For the
sample, which removes contracts greater than $1 million per year, the mean annual contract
price is $43,870 and the median is $13,180. The sample contains 76 contracts with an annual
price greater than $100,000.
Overall, the estimation sample compares favorably to the broader set of cleaning contracts
in the FPDS. For fiscal years 2004 to 2016, an average of 6,366 cleaning contracts are in effect
each year. 95 percent of these have an annual value of less than $1 million. Within this subset,
the mean annual value is $70,322 and the median is $11,200. Cleaning contracts are larger in
16
On a contract-by-contract basis, these outcomes occur at higher rates for building cleaning services. However,
after correcting for the fact that building cleaning contracts last 3 to 4 times longer the typical service contract, the
comparison is reversed. In other words, other services require, on average, 3 to 4 contracts to cover the same period
as a typical building cleaning contract.
17
The initial entry for total contract value in FPDS is systematically underreported, as shown in Appendix D. Thus,
comparing total payments to the initial entry in FPDS would systematically overstate the degree of cost overruns.
16
value than the average contract. For all contracts with an annual value of less than $1 million,
the mean annual value is $35,469 and the median is $4,731. These contracts comprise 97
percent of all contracts in the relevant period, or an average of 1,004,991 each year.
One important source of variation in the analysis is in the number of bids received. The
median is 5 bids, and the maximum is 40. Thus, there is a good deal of competition for these
contracts. The variation in the number of bids will help to disentangle the effect of private costs
from unobserved heterogeneity in the structural analysis.
In the last row, the table provides the number of employees for the winning firms. The
winning firms in this dataset are typically small, with a median of 14 employees. Over 25
percent of the winning suppliers have 3 or fewer employees.
Figure 2 plots the logged values of the winning bids on the y-axis against the number of
bidders on the x-axis. The second panel displays residualized values for the (log) winning
bids. The residuals were constructed from a regression of price on duration, square footage,
cleaning frequency, baseline unemployment, and fixed effects for facility type. Even after con-
trolling for observable characteristics, there is large variation in prices for auctions with many
bidders. The pattern observed in the figure—large variation in prices with clustering at the me-
dian price, rather than the minimum—motivates the assumption of unobserved auction-specific
heterogeneity used in the model. Though much of the variation in prices can be explained by
observables, there is still residual variation that is inconsistent with an independent private
values model; the model with multiplicative common costs fits far better.
The contracts in the dataset have a good deal of variation in duration, ranging from 5
months to 6.5 years, though contracts tend to cluster at yearly increments. Figure 3 provides
a histogram of duration in three-month intervals. Empirical variation in contract duration
occurs within and across government agencies. Consistent with the model, larger facilities and
more frequent cleaning are correlated with shorter contracts, after conditioning on department
and facility type.
18
As a first-pass check that transaction costs matter, contracts issued under
the government’s simplified acquisition protocol, which reduces the ex ante transaction costs,
are 15 percent shorter than other contracts, after conditioning on square footage, cleaning
frequency, and facility type.
Notably, 53 percent of contracts are for 5 years, which is the typical maximum contract
duration imposed by federal budgeting regulations. Longer durations require the contracting
officer to request and justify an extension. The observed variation in duration, combined with
the five-year cap on contract duration, help motivate the counterfactual analysis of Section 6,
where I consider the value of the duration decision compared to standard-duration contracts.
The buildings to be cleaned for each contract are categorized into offices (694), research
facilities (111), medical facilities (61), service centers (59), visitor centers (41), airports (30),
technical facilities (19), accommodations (18), and industrial facilities (13). Offices are split
18
For summary statistics by agency, see Appendix C.3.
17
Figure 2: Price versus Number of Bids
(a) Annual Price
1.0
3.2
10.0
32.0
100.0
316.0
1000.0
10 20 30 40
Number of Bids
Annual Price ($1000, Log Scale)
(b) Residualized Annual Price
−2
−1
0
1
2
10 20 30 40
Number of Bids
Residualized Log Winning Bid
Notes: The figure plots the log annual price against the number of bids received for each
contract. There is a great deal of variation in the annual price, much of which cannot be
explained by observable variables. This is illustrated by the residualized bids in the lower
panel. The R
2
of the regression used to construct the residuals, which includes duration,
square footage, frequency, baseline unemployment, and fixed effects for facility type, is
0.74. It is notable that some of the highest and lowest prices are realized with few bidders.
18
Figure 3: Contract Duration
.1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6
Fraction
1 2 3 4 5 6
Duration (Years)
Notes: The figure displays a histogram of contract duration in 3-month bins. Over half of
the contracts have a five-year duration, which is the maximum duration (by regulation)
without specifically requesting an extension. Contracts are clustered in yearly intervals,
though the support in between full years is relatively well-covered.
into standard offices (424) and field offices (270), which also have an auxiliary building, such
as an exercise room, a bunkhouse, or a small warehouse. Appendix C.2 provides a breakdown
by the issuing agency and by subcategory.
3.4 Descriptive Regressions
To demonstrate the fit between the model and the data and to motivate specific assumptions
made in estimation, I present descriptive regressions. Table 2 provides regressions of the log
annual price on the number of bids, duration, and controls. The first three columns display the
results from ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions. Square footage alone, as reported in the
first specification, captures 62 percent of the variation in prices.
To account for endogenous entry, I instrument for the number of bidders using time-series
and cross-sectional variation in local labor market conditions, as well as variation in the type of
bidders permitted to compete for the contract. The first instrument is the (log) ratio of county-
level unemployment relative to a 2004 baseline. This generates a time-varying county-specific
unemployment shock. The second instrument is the number of establishments for NAICS code
561720 (corresponding to building cleaning services) in the same 3-digit ZIP code.
19
It is
plausible that an increase in unemployment or the presence of more firms in the broader ge-
19
I add 1 to the raw value to use the logged value in estimation, as a few contracts have zero in the raw value.
19
Table 2: Descriptive Regressions: ln(Annual Price)
OLS-1 OLS-2 OLS-3 IV-1 IV-2
ln(Square Footage) 0.730
∗∗∗
0.658
∗∗∗
0.658
∗∗∗
0.689
∗∗∗
0.687
∗∗∗
(0.018) (0.017) (0.017) (0.024) (0.024)
Number of Bids 0.014
∗∗∗
0.009
0.053
∗∗
0.047
∗∗
(0.005) (0.005) (0.022) (0.022)
Duration (Years) 0.041
∗∗∗
0.032
∗∗
0.043
∗∗∗
0.033
∗∗
(0.015) (0.015) (0.016) (0.015)
ln(Weekly Frequency) 0.459
∗∗∗
0.394
∗∗∗
0.467
∗∗∗
0.407
∗∗∗
(0.039) (0.038) (0.041) (0.040)
ln(2004 Unemp.) 0.054
∗∗∗
0.037
∗∗∗
0.080
∗∗∗
0.060
∗∗∗
(0.012) (0.012) (0.019) (0.018)
High-Intensity Cleaning 0.586
∗∗∗
0.559
∗∗∗
(0.071) (0.075)
Building Type FEs X X
Observations 1046 1046 1046 1046 1046
R
2
0.62 0.71 0.74 0.69 0.73
Standard errors in parentheses
p < 0.10,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗∗
p < 0.01
Notes: The table displays estimated coefficients from regressions of log annual price on auction
characteristics. The variables from specification IV-1 are included in the structural model. These
regressions show that square footage, cleaning frequency, and market characteristics explain
much of the variation in prices. Once square footage, cleaning frequency, and market character-
istics are accounted for, fixed effects for location type add little explanatory power. Specifications
IV-1 and IV-2 are two-stage least squares regressions, where the instruments for the number of
bids are monthly (log) county-level unemployment relative to 2004, the (log) number of NAICS
code 561720 establishments in the same 3-digit ZIP code in 2004, and an indicator for whether
the set-aside was for generic small businesses.
ographic area are not driven by unobservable characteristics of these contracts, yet they are
likely to generate increased entry.
A third instrument is developed from the federal government practice of “setting aside” cer-
tain contracts for firms with particular types of owners. Specialized set-asides include women-
owned and veteran-owned small businesses. As we have removed economically disadvantaged
set-asides (e.g., for Economically Disadvantaged Women-Owned Small Business) from the sam-
ple, it is plausible that the ownership type is uncorrelated with the underlying cost structure of
the participating firms. If the cost structure is independent of ownership for these firms, then
the type of set-aside is a valid instrument for price (by affecting entry). This instrument is im-
plemented as a binary variable with the value of 1 if the contract is open to all small businesses,
i.e., the set-aside does not restrict entry based on characteristics of the owner.
The last two columns report the estimated coefficients from instrument variables regres-
sions. Consistent with endogenous entry, I find a larger negative effect of the number of bidders
on price compared to the corresponding OLS specifications. In the structural model of Section
20
Table 3: Descriptive Regressions: Number of Bids
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Duration (Years) 0.104 0.017 0.002 0.002
(0.104) (0.099) (0.099) (0.100)
ln(Square Footage) 0.760
∗∗∗
0.779
∗∗∗
0.834
∗∗∗
0.825
∗∗∗
(0.111) (0.106) (0.106) (0.112)
ln(Weekly Frequency) 0.487
0.081 0.009 0.137
(0.254) (0.247) (0.253) (0.257)
ln(2004 Unemp.) 0.832
∗∗∗
0.794
∗∗∗
0.793
∗∗∗
(0.239) (0.238) (0.238)
ln(Unemployment) 1.415
∗∗∗
1.420
∗∗∗
1.356
∗∗∗
(0.232) (0.231) (0.231)
ln(Num. Firms in Zip3) 0.241 0.257
0.276
(0.148) (0.148) (0.147)
Generic Set-Aside 1.134
∗∗∗
0.987
∗∗∗
(0.350) (0.361)
High-Intensity Cleaning 0.294
(0.475)
Building Type FEs X
Observations 1046 1046 1046 1046
R
2
0.06 0.16 0.17 0.19
F -statistic 22.2 32.0 25.9 14.7
Standard errors in parentheses
p < 0.10,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗∗
p < 0.01
Notes: The table displays estimated coefficients from regressions of the number of
bids on auction characteristics and local labor market variables. Specification (3) is
equivalent to the first-stage regression of IV-1 in Table 2. Specification (4) includes
fixed effects for each building type.
5, I explicitly model entry to account for this endogeneity. The main motivating specification
is IV-1, which uses square footage, weekly cleaning frequency, and baseline (2004) unemploy-
ment as controls. To capture variation in the types of buildings and cleaning required, IV-1
includes an indicator for "high intensity" cleaning of airports and medical buildings. IV-2 in-
cludes indicators for all building types. The inclusion of fixed effects for all types have low in
specifications OLS-3 and IV-2 have a low per-variable impact on R
2
and do not have a substan-
tial effect on the estimated coefficients. Therefore, I omit them from the structural estimation
and proceed with the variables used in IV-1.
20
Though the linear model does not account for the offsetting effects of duration on price
and (via profits) on entry, the regressions capture a positive relationship between price and
20
Each of the three instruments, when used by itself, pushes the coefficient on number of bids more negative and
has little impact on the other coefficients. If separate indicators are estimated for medical buildings and airports,
the coefficients on the indicators are very similar and the coefficients on the other variables are unchanged.
21
duration. This reduced-form correlation is consistent with Proposition 1, which predicts that a
longer duration generates a higher per-period price. Thus, the data match a key distinguishing
feature of the model of optimal duration. In the structural estimation, I also find a positive and
significant direct relationship between duration and price.
In Table 3, I display regressions of the number of bids on auction characteristics and local
measures of unemployment. Specification (3) is equivalent to the first-stage regression in IV-1,
with an F -statistic of 25.9. All three instruments—the unemployment shock, the presence of
existing firms, and a generic set-aside—have the expected positive signs. Though current un-
employment is associated with more bids, higher baseline levels, which are used as a control,
are associated with fewer bids. I interpret the negative correlation between higher 2004 un-
employment and fewer bids as a reflection of local labor market frictions, leading to reduced
competition and higher wages.
4 Empirical Implementation
4.1 Supplier Participation, Bidding, and Equilibrium
In the general model of Section 2, the buyer decides on the contract T with knowledge of
P (T, x, m), the expected price conditional on contract and market characteristics. The buyer’s
expectation is taken over the number of bidders N and the cost realizations for these bidders.
For the empirical analysis, we separately model the participation decision that determines
Pr(N = n|T, x, m) and the market mechanism that determines E[P (n, T, x, m)|N = n]. The
model thus proceeds in three stages: the first stage reflects the buyer’s problem, the second
stage is the participation decision of suppliers, and the third stage is the market mechanism
that determines the chosen supplier and the price.
1st Stage: Duration Decision The buyer observes (x, m, δ) and sets T to minimize the ex-
pected per-period price plus the amortized transaction cost. The buyer’s objective function is:
min
T T
N
X
n=1
(E[P (n, T, x, m)] · Pr(N = n|T, x, m)) +
δ
P
T
k=1
β
k1
. (11)
2nd Stage: Participation Potential entrants observe (T, x, m), entry costs k(m) · ε, and con-
tract cost-shifters h(x). These costs are common across bidders. k(m) and h(x) are observed by
all parties (including the econometrician), but the entry shock ε is only observed by suppliers.
Bidders enter if expected profits exceed entry costs. Profits conditional on participation
depend on total contract costs C
i
· U · h(x). Thus, we make the usual assumption that cost
components are multiplicative. Bidders do not observe the private cost C
i
or the common cost
22
Figure 4: Summary of Model
Price
Contract
Duration
Number
of Bids
Transaction
Costs
Contract
Characteristics
Entry
Conditions
Notes: The figure summarizes the causal assumptions embedded in the empir-
ical model. The three sets of variables on the left: entry conditions, contract
characteristics, and transaction costs, are taken as given. Price, number of
bids, and contract duration are jointly determined in the model. Arrows indi-
cate the direction of causality.
U until after they decide to participate. In this context, U captures unobserved auction-specific
heterogeneity.
Let π
n
denote proportional profits for the n
th
marginal entrant, which depends on C
i
, the
distribution of C, and the number of participating suppliers. Total profits are π
n
· U · h(x). The
entry condition is given by
E[π
n
· U · h(x)|n, T ] k(m) · ε > 0 N n. (12)
3rd Stage: Bidding Participating suppliers realize their private (proportional) cost C
i
and the
common cost U . They then engage in a supplier selection mechanism. For the empirical appli-
cation, we model the mechanism as a first-price auction, though the model can be generalized
to other structures.
We assume bidders are risk neutral. Therefore, in equilibrium, each bidder submits a bid of
b
i
· U · h(x), where b
i
represents the proportional bid for bidder i. The lowest proportional bid,
B, is the winning bid.
Equilibrium is characterized by the buyer choosing duration to minimize expected buyer
costs, potential suppliers entering if expected profits exceed entry costs, and participating sup-
pliers bidding optimally in the market mechanism. The model is summarized in Figure 4.
Relative to a standard auction model with entry, the model also allows for a strategic decision
by the buyer (duration).
23
4.2 Identification of Participation and Bidding
As shown in Section 2, contract-specific transaction costs are identified conditional on P (T, x, m),
using the optimality condition of the buyer. The function P (T, x, m), which captures the partic-
ipation and bidding game, is identified separately. It is identified even if T is not set optimally,
or if T is chosen from a restricted set (e.g., capped a maximum duration).
4.2.1 Identification of Supply Price
The econometrician observes the transaction price P = B · U · h(x) as well as (N, T, x, m). The
cost shocks U, ε, and C are unobserved by the buyer and the econometrician, but their distri-
butions are common knowledge. To achieve nonparametric identification, we make restrictions
on the distributions of unobservables. Assume
(i) Independence of Unobservables: C
i
, U, and ε are independent conditional on (N, T, x, m).
(ii) Mean Independence of Common Shocks: E[ε|T, x, m] = E[ε] and E[U|T, x, m] = E[U].
E[U ] is normalized to 1.
(iii) h(·) and k(·) are continuous, and the range of h(·) or k(·) has broad support. h(x
0
) and
k(m
0
) are normalized to 1 for specific values of x and m.
Importantly, we assume that U is independent of T . In the timing of the model, U is realized
after T is chosen; T depends endogenously on (x, m, δ) but not U. Under these assumptions, it
is straightforward to obtain identification of the expected proportional bid (B), the cost-shifter
functions, and relative profits:
Proposition 5. When (P, N, T, x, m) is observed, the following components of the model are
identified:
1. E[B|N, T, x, m]
2. h(x) and k(m)
3. Relative profits for N and N
0
participants:
E[π
N
|N,T ]
E[π
N
0
|N
0
,T ]
4. Relative profits for T and T
0
with N participants:
E[π
N
|N,T ]
E[π
N
|N,T
0
]
Proof. See Appendix E.
The first two components are sufficient to identify P (T, x, m) and transaction costs, without
using the auction structure for the third stage of the game. Thus, even when the underlying
selection mechanism is unknown, the model can be useful for counterfactual analysis of the
impact of duration and transaction costs.
24
4.2.2 Identification of Profits and the Joint Distribution of Costs
With additional structure on the final mechanism, seller surplus can be identified. This can be
useful in analyzing efficiency and for identification of the full joint distribution of costs. To this
end, in addition to (i)-(iii) we further assume:
(iv) Bidders are symmetric: C
i
F
i
, with F
i
= F for all i.
(v) F is continuous with positive support. U G, where G has positive support.
(vi) Auctions with sequential values of N {N, ..., N } are observed, with N < N.
Proposition 6. When the supplier selection mechanism is an auction with symmetric bidders, seller
surplus is identified.
Proof. See Appendix E.
Variation in N, combined with identification of relative profits, allows for identification of seller
surplus in the auction model.
Once seller surplus (or expected profit) is identified, the distribution of ε is identified from
equation (12), using variation in h or k. Further, we can pin down properties of the private cost
distribution.
Proposition 7. The first (N N + 2) expected order statistics of N draws from F are identified,
providing (N N + 2) restrictions on the private cost distribution.
Proof. See Appendix E.
Intuitively, exogenous variation in N shifts the private cost component of the winning bid,
but not the common costs. Restrictions on the order statistics of F have additional power in that
they may reject many classes of flexible distributions with (N N + 2) parameters. Because the
full set of expected order statistics approximates the quantile function when N is large, exact
nonparametric identification of F is obtained when N = 2 and N .
Corollary 2. The distribution of unobserved heterogeneity is obtained after F is identified.
Proof. By independence, we can use the characteristic function transform to write ϕ
ln W
N
(z) =
ϕ
ln B
N
(z) · ϕ
ln U
, where W
N
= B
N
· U is the observed winning bid scaled by the observables and
B
N
is the distribution of the proportional winning bid conditional on N. We can construct this
function for two different values of N. Once the characteristic function of F is obtained, either
by exact identification (N ) or by flexible estimation methods, G is pinned down.
25
4.2.3 Discussion of Identification Assumptions
In my empirical setting, it is important to account for unobserved auction-specific heterogeneity.
The baseline set of assumptions map to the setting of Krasnokutskaya (2011), while allowing
for endogenous entry. Symmetry is a typical assumption in auction models of unobserved het-
erogeneity (see also, e.g., Aradillas-López et al., 2013). To relax symmetry, one could consider
alternative restrictions to pin down costs and the joint distribution of outcomes. One alternative
would be to employ supplementary data on profits for one (N, T ) pair. This would identify the
expected profit function, which could then be used to identify the joint distribution of costs.
21
Another common assumption is that bidders realize some auction-specific costs after decid-
ing to participate. This assumption may a reasonable approximation in this setting because
observables explain roughly 70 percent of the variation in prices. One could relax this as-
sumption by allowing bidders to select into the auction based on observing U beforehand. In
this case, it is straightforward to extend the identification results. Additional steps would be
required if potential bidders observed their private cost draw before deciding to participate.
These assumptions are sufficient for the nonparametric identification of the auction model.
In effect, the entry cost shifters m serve as instruments for the number of bidders. Exogenous
variation in N is then used to separately identify private costs from unobserved heterogeneity.
With no instruments, these distributions can still be separately identified. Therefore, with
unobserved heterogeneity and conditionally independent private values (i.e., the setting of
Krasnokutskaya, 2011), the model is identified with data on only the winning bid and variation
in the number of bidders. I provide this alternative identification approach in Appendix E.5.
Under maintained assumptions, the buyer makes the duration decision based on observable
characteristics of the contract (e.g., square footage and cleaning frequency) and the market
(e.g., unemployment and local number of firms), as well as transaction costs. Thus, after
conditioning on contract and market characteristics, variation in contract duration is driven by
unobserved transaction costs. We can then estimate the price schedule by observing contracts
with similar characteristics that vary in duration. For example, if we observe two contracts for
similar office buildings at different agencies, we attribute a difference in duration to different
transaction costs between the agencies, rather than different costs of cleaning the facilities.
4.3 Parameterizations
For the empirical application, I estimate the model of Section 4.2, where bidders are symmetric
and participate in a first-price auction. I employ a parametric approach for parsimony. The
nonparametric identification results provided earlier, along with robustness checks, suggest that
first-order features of the estimated distributions are not entirely driven by functional form. In
this application, there is an added complication of estimating a duration-dependent distribution
21
I test for the presence of asymmetry in Section 5.4. The results are consistent with symmetric bidders.
26
Table 4: Empirical Parameterizations
Cost Component Notation Parameterization
Private Costs C
i
W eibull(µ
0
+ µ
1
T, α
0
+ α
1
T )
Unobserved Heterogeneity U ln N (
σ
2
U
2
, σ
2
U
)
Entry Shock ε ln N (µ
ε
, σ
2
ε
)
Observed Heterogeneity h(x) = square_f ootage
γ
1
· weekly_frequency
γ
2
·2004_unemployment
γ
3
· γ
[high-intensity_cleaning]
4
Entry Costs k(m) = T · square_footage
κ
1
· weekly_frequency
κ
2
·unemployment_shock
κ
3
· establishments
κ
4
·κ
[generic_set-aside]
5
of private costs, which would increase the number of parameters needed for any nonparametric
approach.
The parameterizations are given in Table 4. A central consideration of this paper is that
the distribution of the average per-period private cost, C
i
, changes with the duration of the
contract. One approach to estimation would be to estimate a microfounded model where the
per-period cost shocks are governed by an autocorrelation parameter. Instead, I estimate the
average per-period cost distribution as a primitive, allowing the mean of the average per-period
cost and the variance to vary with T . As I am not taking a stand on the underlying cost process,
I estimate a “reduced-form” primitive for the cost distribution. By picking an appropriately
flexible distribution, this approach may better approximate a wider range of per-period distri-
butional families.
22
For private costs, the Weibull distribution is chosen for tractability and flexibility, as it allows
the estimated probability density functions to be either convex or concave. It is governed by the
mean parameter µ(T ) = µ
0
+ µ
1
T and the shape parameter α(T ) = α
0
+ α
1
T . I allow the pa-
rameters of the private cost distribution to vary linearly with duration to capture the first-order
effects of interest in this model. A finding of α
1
> 0 is consistent with autocorrelation in cost
shocks, which results in reduced variance in average per-period costs over longer contracts. For
the distribution of unobserved heterogeneity, the log-normal distribution was chosen because
it best fit the model out of several choices.
23
In the first step, I estimate the parameters for participation and bidding using maximum
likelihood. In this step, I do not require that the choice of duration is optimal. The fact that
observed duration may be capped or otherwise chosen from a restricted set does not affect
the parameter estimates. Entry costs shocks are parameterized as increasing linearly with the
22
For an example microfounded model, see Appendix F.
23
Other estimated distributions of unobserved heterogeneity were the gamma distribution and the Weibull distri-
bution. Both have the desirable properties of support on (0, ) and can be normalized to have a mean of 1.
27
duration of the contract.
24
Note that square footage and weekly frequency can affect the entry
decision by both increasing supply costs (price) and affecting entry costs.
One of the challenges in the estimation of auction models arises from the computational
burden of inverting the bid function. I employ a simple innovation—a change of variables—
which circumvents this step and greatly speeds up estimation in the presence of unobserved
heterogeneity. This innovation and details of the likelihood function are in Appendix G.
In a second step, I use the estimated parameters in the buyer’s objective function (equation
(11)) to generate nonparametric bounds on δ for each contract, following the steps in Section
2.3. In my data, contracts are either set to the nearest monthly or nearest yearly increment,
providing a set of tight and loose bounds, respectively. That is, if I observe a 16-month contract,
I assume it was preferred to 15-month and 17-month contracts, whereas I assume that a 24-
month contract was preferred to other yearly increments (12-month and 36-month contracts).
I estimate these transaction costs with an annual discount rate of β = 0.97. A smaller value
of β would imply higher transaction costs. This is because the β-dependent components of the
bounds given by equations (9) and (10) are decreasing in β, for β < 1. Intuitively, a smaller
β corresponds to a smaller marginal benefit for a longer contract. This, in turn, implies that a
greater transaction cost is needed to rationalize the chosen duration.
Finally, to construct expected market transaction costs and conduct counterfactuals, I apply
a uniform prior for the density between the distribution-free bounds.
25
Using the prior, I con-
struct point estimates by taking the expectation. In practice, many of the contracts in my data
face a cap on maximum duration of five years, due to federal regulation. For contracts affected
by the cap, only a lower bound for δ can be obtained without additional assumptions. I make
the assumption that the chosen duration at five years is optimal. This generates a relatively
conservative upper bound on transaction costs. Many of the optimal contracts under a higher
cap would be likely be longer, implying a larger upper bound and larger point estimates for the
transaction costs.
5 Results
Estimation of the structural model proceeds in three steps. First, I use a parametric maximum
likelihood to perform joint estimation of entry and bidding. Second, using the duration decision
of the buyer and estimated parameters from the first step, I construct distribution-free bounds
for transaction costs. Third, I construct estimates of transaction costs by applying a prior over
24
This has the interpretation that entry costs are borne annually and could reflect the opportunity costs of other
contracts. Allowing a free parameter on the entry costs in estimation generates a coefficient close to one.
25
The uniform prior is appealing for its transparency and also for the reason that the observed duration is optimal
at the mean transaction cost when buyers can issue contracts in monthly increments. If a left triangular prior
were used instead, the optimal monthly-increment contract would be shorter than the observed value for contracts
observed in yearly increments.
28
Table 5: Parameter Estimates
Group Parameter Variable Estimate 95 Percent C.I.
Private Costs µ
0
- 18.521 [16.658, 20.861]
µ
1
Duration 0.546 [0.085, 0.979]
α
0
- 4.807 [3.527, 6.969]
α
1
Duration 0.386 [0.053, 0.674]
Heterogeneity σ
U
- 0.608 [0.572, 0.646]
γ
1
Square Footage 0.664 [0.627, 0.701]
γ
2
Weekly Frequency 0.488 [0.411, 0.556]
γ
3
2004 Unemployment 0.087 [0.070, 0.106]
γ
4
High-Intensity Cleaning 0.302 [0.187, 0.437]
Entry µ
ε
- 0.459 [-0.749, -0.173]
σ
ε
- 0.649 [0.608, 0.687]
κ
1
Square Footage 0.543 [0.488, 0.599]
κ
2
Weekly Frequency 0.542 [0.420, 0.650]
κ
3
Unemployment Shock 0.309 [-0.449, -0.208]
κ
4
Establishments 0.066 [-0.108, -0.025]
κ
5
Generic Set-Aside 0.262 [-0.390, -0.148]
Notes: The table displays maximum likelihood parameter estimates from the structural model. The first group
of coefficients indicate how the mean and shape of the private cost distribution change with the duration of the
contract. The second set of coefficients indicate the distribution of unobserved auction-specific heterogeneity
and how auction-specific common costs vary with observable cost characteristics. The third set of coefficients
pertain to entry costs in the model. 95 percent confidence intervals are displayed in the last column. As minor
data cleaning steps (de-meaning) are data-dependent, confidence intervals are constructed via 500 bootstrap
samples.
the bounds. These estimates are inputs to the policy counterfactuals presented in Section 6.
The estimation steps are described in more detail in Section 4.
5.1 Estimated Supply Costs and Entry Costs
Table 5 displays the parameter estimates from the first step. Square footage, weekly frequency,
and 2004 unemployment are scaled by the mean, so that the estimate of µ
0
is interpreted as
the mean annual private cost draw for a zero-duration contract at a typical location. The mean
annual private cost is $18,521 and increases by 2.9 percent per contract year (µ
1
0
).
26
Thus,
I find that the data are consistent with the equilibrium prediction from Proposition 1. Prices
increase with duration due to both the increase in mean costs and the reduction in variance, as
we would expect if cost shocks are not perfectly correlated over time. The reduction in variance
is captured by the positive coefficient α
1
.
As expected, higher values for square footage and weekly frequency increase costs. Con-
26
For a visual representation of how costs depend on duration, I plot the density of private cost draws for a
one-year and a five-year contract in Appendix H.1.
29
Figure 5: Model Fit: Actual Versus Predicted Annual Price
1.0
3.2
10.0
32.0
100.0
316.0
1000.0
1.0 3.2 10.0 32.0 100.0 316.0 1000.0
Predicted Price from Model ($1000s, Log Scale)
Annual Price ($1000s, Log Scale)
Notes: The figure plots observed prices against predicted prices from the model. The R
2
of
the predicted values is 0.71, which compares favorably to the R
2
of 0.69 from the linear
instrumental variables model.
sistent with the findings from the descriptive regressions, baseline unemployment and high-
intensity buildings have higher costs. For entry, higher current unemployment and the presence
of more local establishments lower entry costs. Generic set-asides also have lower entry costs,
relative to demographic-specific set-asides. Square footage has a net positive effect on entry,
as γ
1
> κ
1
. Supply costs, which are positively correlated with profits, increase by more than
entry costs for square footage. Weekly frequency, on the other hand, has a net negative effect
on entry, as γ
2
< κ
2
. This is consistent with capacity constraints, as some firms may be limited
in the days they are available to clean. The mean per-bidder entry cost estimate is $573.
The model fits the data well. In Figure 5, I display actual values for annual prices compared
to the predicted values. The R
2
for the structural model is 0.71, which compares favorably to
the linear model IV-1 in Table 2. Unobserved heterogeneity is important to match the distri-
bution of prices. Unobserved common costs are economically meaningful, in that they capture
approximately 30 percent of the variance of log prices.
5.2 Estimated Transaction Costs
Market transaction costs are significant in this setting, comprising 10.9 percent of annual costs.
These costs capture the marginal costs to the federal government of running a procurement
auction, and they are summarized in Table 6. To obtain the aggregate share of costs attributable
to transaction costs, I divide the mean annualized transaction costs by the mean total annual
30
Table 6: Estimated Market Transaction Costs ($)
Contract-Specific Measure Median 95 Percent C.I. p25 p75 Mean
Transaction Costs 10,400 [3,000, 17,400] 5,100 21,400 24,500
Annualized 2,500 [700, 4,100] 1,300 4,800 5,400
Contract Value 50,500 [46,900, 54,100] 28,500 102,000 190,200
Price (Annual) 13,200 [12,300, 13,900] 7,300 26,700 43,900
Percent Share of Costs 15.2 [5.0, 22.0] 9.9 20.8 16.3
Aggregate Measure Estimate 95 Percent C.I.
Percent Share of Costs 10.9 [3.8, 20.3]
Notes: Estimated transaction costs are the expectation taken with a uniform prior over the distribution-free
bounds identified from the duration decision of the buyer. For T = 5, conservative upper bounds are projected
by assuming that the duration is optimally chosen. Transaction costs are also expressed as a share of total
(buyer) costs. The aggregate share of total costs attributable to transaction costs is 10.9 percent, which is
calculated by comparing the mean annualized transaction costs to the mean price. Confidence intervals are
constructed via the bootstrap. For display, values are rounded to the nearest 100.
cost (the sum of annualized transaction costs and the price). Also displayed in the table are
the median values for transaction costs, the annualized values, and the corresponding medians
for contract value and price. The median transaction cost is estimated to be $10,400, and
the median share of costs attributable to transaction costs is 15 percent across contracts. The
estimated magnitudes seem reasonable based on some back-of-the-envelope calculations, which
I discuss in the following section.
The sequential, revealed-preference approach has the benefit of providing testable impli-
cations of the model via the unconstrained estimates presented here. A finding of negative
transaction costs, which would arise with private costs that fall with duration, would suggest
that the tradeoff in this paper is not first-order to contract duration. Instead, the 95 percent
confidence intervals of µ
1
and α
1
have positive support, implying positive transaction costs only,
which is consistent with the model. As previously, the premium on duration can arise simply
from averaging cost draws across multiple periods. The premium captures opportunity costs as
well, reflecting the seller’s beliefs about the arrival rate of more profitable options.
In some cases, the market transaction costs are quite large as a percent of total costs. The
95th percentile of share of costs attributable to market transaction costs is 32.3 percent. For
these estimates, this is driven by moderate transaction costs realized by low-price projects,
rather than very high absolute costs. For example, contracts with a portion of transaction costs
in the 95th percentile or above (greater than 32.3 percent) have a mean price of $9,000, which
is much smaller than the full-sample mean of $43,900.
31
5.3 Verifying the Estimated Transaction Costs
To check the magnitudes of the estimated transaction costs, we can perform a back-of-the-
envelope calculation by looking at the labor costs of employees who specialize in contracting,
purchasing, and procurement.
27
Considering only these specialists will understate the full labor
costs of managing contracts, as employees in several other categories are involved in issuing
contracts. These other categories include supply program managers, logistics managers, and
support service administrators, who all perform other tasks in addition to procurement, as well
as specialists with industrial, engineering, or scientific knowledge who assist in determining the
requirements for the contract.
28
The labor costs for contract specialists provide a reasonable benchmark for relatively simple
products and services. Large and complex contracts require more input from subject-matter ex-
perts and from consumers of the product or service, which will not be captured by the measure.
Another consideration is that some contracts require ongoing maintenance by the contracting
agency, so a portion of labor costs do not reflect the one-time costs of new contracts. For sim-
ple contracts, the labor costs of contracting officers is likely a close approximation of these
otherwise hidden costs, as most of the effort is made up front.
For a new contract, the contracting officer must draft the requirements,
29
survey the market
and decide terms, ensure compliance with existing regulations, post the solicitation, commu-
nicate with interested bidders, determine the winning bidder, and conclude the contract. A
senior contracting officer for the federal government estimated that the simplest cleaning con-
tract would take about three weeks of full-time work for a contracting employee. For fiscal
years 2004 to 2016, the average salary for contracting specialists was $78,253. Three weeks of
full-time work, assuming a 50-week year, provides a cost estimate of $4,695, which is roughly
in line with the 25th percentile estimate.
Looking at the contracts in aggregate provides another rough benchmark for transaction
costs. To compare to the estimation sample, I examine all contracts for fiscal years 2004 to 2016
that had an annual price of less than $1 million. Approximately 750,000 of these contracts
are issued each year, or 99 percent of all new contracts. These contracts are modestly less
expensive than the estimation sample, with a mean annual price of $35,469 and a median of
$4,731. Overall, 19.8 new contracts per contracting specialist are issued each year. Allocating
the salaries of contracting specialists across new contracts obtains an labor cost of $3,953 per
contract, or 7.7 percent of total buyer costs.
30
These two calculations provide benchmarks that
27
These correspond to GS-1102, GS-1105, and GS-1106 in the federal government’s classification system.
28
The classifications corresponding to the administrative roles are GS-2003, GS-0346, GS-0342. Those pertain-
ing to industrial, engineering, or scientific knowledge are GS-1150, GS-0800, GS-1300, and GS-0400. The stan-
dards may be obtained here: https://www.opm.gov/policy-data-oversight/classification-qualifications/classifying-
general-schedule-positions/.
29
The main document for the median contract runs 49 pages. See Appendix C.4 for example pages.
30
If we instead assumed that new contracts over $1 million required five times the contracting specialists com-
pared to these smaller contracts, then the labor cost per new contract is $3,805, or 7.4 percent of total buyer costs.
32
Table 7: Estimated Market Transaction Costs by Category
(a) Median Values by Location Type
Type Transaction Costs Contract Value Square Footage Count
Medical 38,900 206,000 10,000 61
Airport 32,850 254,300 7,850 30
Technical 30,600 84,000 15,600 19
Industrial 28,500 60,000 27,900 13
Accommodations 28,350 121,200 32,000 18
Services 18,400 87,700 8,300 59
Research 13,400 58,500 6,000 111
Visitors 13,000 189,700 6,500 41
Field Office 9,250 48,500 8,450 270
Office 7,300 35,550 4,750 424
(b) Median Values by Department
Department Transaction Costs Contract Value Square Footage Count
Homeland Security 40,000 269,300 14,600 45
GSA 29,350 223,100 12,750 40
Veterans Affairs 24,450 143,550 8,800 80
Other 20,900 69,200 11,650 24
Commerce 14,150 59,750 5,500 78
Interior 11,900 71,000 8,900 43
Agriculture 9,500 46,700 9,300 347
Defense 7,300 35,900 4,200 389
Notes: The table displays the median estimated market transaction costs. Also displayed are the
median contract value, the median square footage of the facility, and the count of observations.
In panel (a), observations are grouped by location type. In panel (b), observations are grouped
by contracting department. For display, underlying values are rounded to the nearest 100.
are the same order of magnitude of the transaction costs recovered in estimation.
As an additional exercise to check the plausibility of the estimated market transaction costs,
I project the estimates on other variables not used in the structural estimation. First, I calculate
the median transaction costs by facility type and by department in Table 7. As expected, the
highest transaction costs are among facilities with relatively complicated or technical require-
ments, such as medical centers, airports, and technical facilities (e.g., power plants). Simpler
settings such as office cleaning have the lowest estimated transaction costs. In the second panel,
I calculate the median by government department. The Department of Homeland Security has
the highest median transaction costs, at $40,000 per contract. This might be expected given the
high levels of security required at their facilities and the relative lack of institutional knowledge
75 percent of contracts under $1 million and 29 percent of larger contracts are new each year, based on the latter
half of the data (FY 2011-16). Larger contracts likely involve significant resources from other employee classifica-
tions. The 3 percent of contracts over $1 million annually (31,929 each year on average) comprise over 90 percent
of all dollars obligated. When including this long tail, the aggregate labor cost per contract from contracting special-
ists is less than one percent of total costs. Larger contracts likely involve significant resources from other employee
classifications.
33
Table 8: Projecting Market Transaction Costs on Variables Outside of the Model
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
High-Intensity Cleaning 1.448
∗∗∗
1.189
∗∗∗
1.140
∗∗∗
1.022
∗∗∗
1.158
∗∗∗
0.612
∗∗∗
(0.144) (0.133) (0.134) (0.138) (0.138) (0.108)
ln(Word Count) 0.085
∗∗∗
0.124
∗∗∗
0.043
∗∗
(0.024) (0.023) (0.018)
ln(Related Expenditures) 0.096
∗∗∗
0.073
∗∗∗
0.054
∗∗∗
(0.011) (0.023) (0.017)
ln(Related Modifications) 0.283
∗∗∗
0.047 0.141
∗∗
(0.035) (0.071) (0.055)
Simplified Acquisition Ind. 0.692
∗∗∗
0.715
∗∗∗
0.429
∗∗∗
(0.090) (0.089) (0.069)
ln(Square Footage) 0.577
∗∗∗
(0.026)
ln(Weekly Frequency) 0.510
∗∗∗
(0.057)
Observations 1046 1046 1046 1046 1046 1046
R
2
0.09 0.14 0.13 0.13 0.20 0.54
Standard errors in parentheses
p < 0.10,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗∗
p < 0.01
Notes: The table displays estimated coefficients from regressing estimated log transaction costs on variables
outside of the model. These variables are (i) the (log) number of pages in the contract, (ii) log government
procurement expenditures at the same 9-digit ZIP code for maintenance, office furniture, and other housekeeping
services, (iii) the count of contract actions for these expenditures, and (iv) an indicator for whether the contract
falls under the federal government’s simplified acquisition protocol.
at the recently-formed department.
31
Conversely, Agriculture and Defense have low median
transaction costs, at $9,500 and $7,300, respectively. After controlling for square footage,
cleaning frequency, and facility type in a regression, Homeland Security has the highest fixed
effect for (log) transaction costs, 91 percent larger than Defense. Agriculture has lowest fixed
effect, 17 percent smaller than Defense. The regression table is provided in Appendix H.2.
In Table 8, I regress the estimated market transaction costs on variables excluded from
the structural model. Included covariates are the number of pages in the contract, related
expenditures and contract modifications
32
in the same 9-digit ZIP code, and an indicator for
whether the contract falls under the simplified acquisition protocol. One would expect that
lengthier contracts and busier agencies are reflective of higher opportunity costs, and that the
simplified acquisition label would reflect lower market transaction costs. After controlling for
square footage and cleaning frequency, high-expenditure locations are associated with higher
transaction costs. Economic theory could rationalize a sign in either direction, as economies
31
Contracting employees in Homeland Security had lower length of service and were less likely to have a bachelor
degree compared to the average contracting employee.
32
Related expenditure categories are other housekeeping services, maintenance, and office furniture.
34
of scale lead to a positive association and capacity constraints produce a negative one. The
negative coefficient on contract modifications in the fifth specification may reflect economics of
scale or simply that lower transaction costs lead to more contract modifications.
Though understanding the precise composition of these costs requires further study, the
analysis above and some supplemental data allow us to (very roughly) speculate about the
breakdown of these costs. Table 8 shows that, controlling for other features of the contract,
simplified acquisition procedures are associated with 35 percent lower transaction costs (-0.429
log points). Contracts made under simplified acquisition do not require (a) market research,
(b) conducting discussions with potential vendors, and (c) establishing a formal source selec-
tion team. The bidding mechanism itself (d) may constitute around 1 percent of the total value
of the contract, or 10 percent of the transaction costs. For example, FedBid, one of the leading
auction platform providers for the federal government, charges “no more than 3 percent of the
winning bid.” Anecdotally, a fee of around 1 percent of the winning bid is not unusual for
external auction platforms. Therefore, these first four components may make up about 45 per-
cent of transaction costs. The bulk of the residual is likely allocated to (e) deciding on contract
terms and (f) checking that the contract specifications are up-to-date with current regulations.
Contracting officers may copy and paste text from a previous contract, but there is a signifi-
cant burden to ensure that the contracts are in compliance. The Federal Acquisition Regulation
(FAR) that governs these contracts is over 2,000 pages and frequently references other legal
code, such as federal employment regulations. Finally, other costs include (g) marketing the
opportunity to potential vendors and (h) documenting each step according to FAR.
Again, I emphasize that these breakdowns are very rough. They are intended to illustrate
the different components that constitute ex ante transaction costs, rather than providing exact
empirical quantities. The literature on this front is sparse, and deeper analysis of these costs is
a potential avenue for future research.
5.4 Robustness
To estimate the model, I have followed typical practice in the empirical literature, such as
assuming multiplicative separability in cost components. For the discount rate and for five-year
contracts, I have made assumptions that generate conservative estimates of transaction costs.
For a discussion of these choices and sensitivity to specific parameterizations, see Section 4.3.
For the empirical model, we have proceeded under the assumption that bidders are sym-
metric with respect to private supply costs. In a dynamic setting, the procurement process
might result in asymmetry between bidders that would invalidate this assumption. One com-
mon source of asymmetry in procurement is the presence of an incumbent bidder who may
have an advantage via a relationship-specific investment (e.g., through learning-by-doing or
lowered transaction costs of retaining the same supplier). Additionally, competing bidders may
retain some information about competitors if costs are correlated over time.
35
Table 9: Test for Asymmetry: Do Incumbents Have an Advantage?
Follow-On Contracts Symmetric Win Rate Incumbent Win Rate N t-Statistic
Estimation Sample 0.224 0.217 175 (0.20)
Extended FPDS Sample 0.278 0.263 845 (1.00)
Notes: The table displays the results of a test for asymmetry in performance by incumbent bidders. The
expected win rate for symmetric bidders, based on the number of bids, is compared to the observed win rate
by incumbent bidders. The t-statistics indicate no significant difference in either sample. The first sample
is follow-on contracts in the estimation sample, and the second sample uses the same criteria for all FPDS
building cleaning contracts. Follow-on contracts are identified as contracts that have a single leading contract
for the same agency in the same nine-digit ZIP code. A leading contract is one that is active in the year prior
to the start of the follow-on contract and begins at least thirty days prior to the start of the follow-on contract.
I check for the presence of asymmetries by comparing the expected win rate under symmetry
(based on the number of bidders) to the win rate for incumbent suppliers in follow-on contract.
I identify follow-on contracts in the analysis sample by finding contracts that have a single active
supplier on another contract in the same 9-digit ZIP code within the prior year (and starting at
least thirty days before). 9-digit ZIP codes are geographically narrow, typically corresponding
to a city block or an individual company. The prior contract may be any of the approximately
11,000 cleaning contracts in the FPDS data. I also construct a broader set of follow-on contracts
from the extended FPDS sample.
Table 9 compares the expected win rate for symmetric bidders to the actual win rate for
incumbent bidders in identified follow-on contracts. There is no significant difference between
the two, suggesting that the incumbency advantage is not first-order in this setting. I obtain
similar results for the 175 contracts in the estimation sample and the 845 contracts from the
broader FPDS sample.
33
There are a priori reasons to believe that the incumbency advantage is
not large for competitive federal procurement, as, per regulation, the agencies are mandated to
seriously consider all qualified bidders and, in most cases, select the lowest price. The degree of
relationship-specific investments in facility cleaning is likely to be low, as the menu of services
tend to be standardized.
Transaction costs do not appear to depend on whether the winning bidder is an incumbent.
For follow-on contracts, there is no difference in mean (log) transaction costs between contracts
that are won by an incumbent (2.277, N = 38) and those that are not (2.274, N = 137). As an
additional test, I include a dummy for whether the contract is an identified follow-on contract
in the descriptive regressions from Section 3 to determine if variation in prices and entry are
explained by the presence of an incumbent bidder. None of the coefficients on the dummy are
significant, and its inclusion does not meaningfully change any of the coefficients of interest.
For these regressions, see Appendix H.3. The results of these tests are consistent with the
maintained assumption of no endogenous asymmetries.
33
As I only observe winning bidders, I am unable to adjust for when a supplier does not bid on a follow-on to the
supplier’s current contract.
36
An additional general concern might be that there is heterogeneity in supplier types. The
above tests for endogenous asymmetries are also valid tests for exogenous asymmetries in sup-
plier types. Lower-cost types would be more likely to win the first contract in the identified set
of follow-on contracts, thereby generating a correlation in win rates over time. Thus, the above
findings are consistent with symmetry across suppliers more generally. In contrast to many
other industries, there is no great distinguishing factor that separates types of building-cleaning
firms, and it is reasonable to expect that production is roughly constant returns-to-scale. This
makes the empirical setting a nice fit for the model.
Finally, an implicit assumption of the empirical model is perfect alignment between the
government and the contracting officer; i.e., there is no principal-agent problem in determining
duration. If we instead suppose that the contracting officer does not fully internalize the price
of the contract to the government (but does bear the market transaction costs), then we would
obtain the same estimates. In this case, the estimated transaction costs have a shadow cost
interpretation: they represent the relevant ex ante costs to the government, but they are greater
than the direct transaction costs due to misaligned incentives.
34
Empirically, one could estimate
misalignment by interpreting the agency-specific fixed effects from the previous section as a
measure of misaligned incentives. If we assume that the agency with the smallest fixed effect
for transaction costs has perfect alignment, then the average agency treats the contract price at
82 cents on the dollar, and the direct transaction costs are 9.1 percent of total buyer costs.
5.5 Generalizability
The estimated transaction costs are obtained in a specialized setting which allows them to be
isolated from other factors. It may be reasonable to translate these costs to federal contracts for
other standardized products, where the buyer’s problem is similar. As discussed in Section 3,
cleaning contracts are comparable in magnitudes to the 97 percent of federal contracts under
$1 million per year. An appealing feature about the application is that the large variation in
observables allows us to account for how these costs vary with project scale and complexity.
In the private sector, many of the components that make up ex ante transaction costs are still
relevant: market research, writing up specifications, marketing the opportunity, and running a
34
In the case of ex ante misalignment, the contracting officer solves
min
T T
ω · P (T, x, m) +
δ
P
T
k=1
β
k1
, (13)
where ω < 1 captures misalignment between the contracting officer and the government. The problem may be
re-written as
min
T T
P (T, x, m) +
δ
P
T
k=1
β
k1
. (14)
Applying this model, we would obtain the same estimates for transaction costs, though we would instead capture
the shadow cost to the government,
δ
ω
, or the transaction costs scaled by the degree of misalignment between the
contracting officer and the government. I thank two anonymous referees for this suggestion.
37
mechanism to determine the winner. Buyers may be able to avoid regulation and compliance
costs that are specific to federal government procurement; since these appear to be sizable
for federal contracts, these might result in meaningfully lower transaction costs in the private
sector. On the other hand, the size of government procurement may provide some economies
of scale and reduce these costs. The federal government can use an existing platform (FedBi-
zOpps) to post each solicitation, so the estimated transaction costs exclude the fixed costs of
setting up such a platform.
Another consideration is that the federal regulations are designed to minimize poor decision-
marking by the contracting officers. Because the private sector has fewer restrictions, the po-
tential for misalignment between the buying agent and the firm may be greater. This can
be reflected in the terms, the type of competitive procedure, or the contractual arrangement.
Based on conversations with procurement officers from several organizations, transaction costs
of around 10 percent of total costs is not an unreasonable estimate in the private sector, though
there is a great deal of heterogeneity in procurement efficiency and the data are sparse.
35
The nature of supply costs is an important consideration in more general contexts. With
building cleaning services, supply is stable over time, and the service represents a small fraction
of overall expenditures. In other settings, such as technology-dependent firms, the per-period
supply costs may be falling over time. Whether or not this feature leads to shorter contracts
depends on whether cost-reducing innovations are predictable and whether they are driven
by high-cost or low-cost firms. Furthermore, buyers may not be risk-neutral with respect to a
primary input that is specialized to their business, which is another factor to consider when
taking the model to other settings. Even so, the tradeoff I identify here remains relevant.
6 Counterfactuals: The Impact of the Duration Margin
I now consider the implications of the endogenous duration decision on welfare. In the first
counterfactual, I analyze the cost to the buyer of removing the ability to adjust duration through
standard contracting terms. In the second counterfactual, I show how duration provides a
margin of adjustment that mediates the pass-through of cost shocks to prices.
6.1 Strategic Value of the Duration Decision, Compared to Standardization
When the buyer can adjust the non-price terms of a contract, the buyer can minimize expected
costs for each transaction. This flexibility provides a cost-minimizing advantage to the firm.
35
In one example, a private university describes a nine-month process to obtain a one-year discount contract on
microscope light bulbs: “Selection of the Preferred Vendor was the culmination of 9 month process managed by Pur-
chasing in cooperation with the Office for Research. It involved surveying the research community to assess needs,
submitting an RFQ to vendors, interviewing vendors, and negotiating price and service... Purchasing was able to ne-
gotiate a substantial reduction in price for one year.” https://www.northwestern.edu/procurement/about/dollars-
sense-newsletter/DSFall2015.pdf
38
Table 10: Effects of Standardized Terms (Percent)
¯
T Total Cost 95 Percent C.I. Price Trans. Cost Affected Compensating δ
1 36.7 [12.1, 55.3] 11.9 354.0 1018 60.9
2 9.9 [3.2, 15.0] 8.0 127.0 992 33.0
3 3.2 [1.0, 4.8] 4.2 51.3 907 16.0
4 1.4 [0.5, 2.4] 0.4 13.5 992 9.4
5 1.6 [0.5, 2.8] 3.2 9.2 496 13.0
6 2.7 [0.8, 4.4] 6.8 24.3 1041 26.6
Notes: The table displays the resulting percent changes in total costs, prices, and annualized transaction
costs when all contracts are issued in standardized durations corresponding to
¯
T . For a uniform duration
policy of 4 years or less, the average price paid decreases and the amount spent on transaction costs
increases. Affected contracts are the count of those that are displaced from the optimal duration. The
final column displays the reduction in transaction costs that would render a uniform policy equivalent
to the existing policy in terms of buyer costs. Confidence intervals are reported for total costs and are
constructed via the bootstrap.
In many settings, contract terms are standardized. For example, a three-year contract is the
industry standard for office supplies. The structural model allows us to estimate how costly it is
to remove the buyer’s strategic option to adjust duration. One may also interpret these impacts
as the costs of going to the market more or less frequently.
Table 10 reports the impact on aggregate buyer costs by moving to standardized terms of
yearly increments. Total costs would increase substantially, by 37 percent, if all contracts were
issued in one-year terms. This is not surprising, as the median duration in the data is 5 years and
standardization would result in much more frequent contracting. On the other hand, standard
durations of 4 years or 5 years would have a small impact, increasing buyer costs by less than
two percent.
These results suggest that flexible terms may be quite valuable, compared to a poorly-chosen
standard (e.g., one year or two years in this setting). Thus, knowledge of the relevant cost
structure and transaction costs is important for setting non-price terms. This analysis further
highlights the importance of the duration margin.
36
To provide additional context on these magnitudes, I calculate the reduction in transaction
costs that would be required to offset the increase in supply costs from standardization. This
may be relevant to a firm that is considering a new contracting process that requires standard-
ized terms but also reduces the transaction costs for each contract. In the final column of Table
10, I report the compensating change in transaction costs that would make the standardized
term policy equivalent to the flexible term policy. For a four-year standard term, the necessary
36
A related question to standardized terms is that of a cap on maximum duration, similar to the five-year cap
imposed by government-wide budgeting regulations in my data. This is analogous to the imposition of standard
terms on only a subset of contracts. In Appendix H.4, I provide a detailed breakdown of the effects by whether
duration is increased or decreased by the standard, which provides insight into the cost of the cap. Table 20 reports
averages by contract, rather than in aggregate, which is why the numbers differ slightly from those in Table 10.
39
Table 11: Effects of a 10 Percent Reduction in Supply Costs (Percent)
Specification Price Duration Total Cost
No Response in Entry or Duration -10.00 0.00 -8.67
[-10.00, -10.00] [0.00, 0.00] [-9.53, -8.01]
Endogenous Entry Only -8.59 0.00 -7.45
[-8.92, -8.14] [0.00, 0.00] [-8.23, -6.85]
Endogenous Entry and Duration -7.70 6.64 -7.50
[-8.33, -7.04] [5.86, 9.63] [-8.26, -6.92]
Notes: The table reports the equilibrium changes to prices, duration, and total costs when supply costs
fall by 10 percent. In the first row, entry and contract duration are treated as exogenous. In the second
row, entry by potential bidders changes in response to supply costs. In the last row, both entry and
contract duration respond endogenously. The first column shows the effects on price. The estimate
divided by -10 percent captures the pass-through of supply costs to prices in each scenario. Confidence
intervals are constructed via the bootstrap.
reduction in transaction costs is modest. If the government could implement a process that
required standard durations of four years and reduced transaction costs by 10 percent, it would
be beneficial to do so.
6.2 Contract Duration and Welfare Analysis
Transaction costs are important to welfare analysis as they can constitute a substantial portion
of total costs and affect how equilibrium prices respond to a change in the economic environ-
ment. When transaction costs are unaffected by a policy change, a welfare analysis that omits
transaction costs will misstate the impact for two reasons. First, the measured impact on prices
should be weighted by the share of total costs attributable to prices. That is, the impact should
be discounted toward zero by the share attributable to (unaffected) transaction costs. Second,
market participants adjust equilibrium behavior in response to the change. The choice of dura-
tion provides an additional margin of adjustment, mitigating the effect on prices but improving
welfare compared to an analysis that takes duration as fixed.
To demonstrate these effects, I calculate equilibrium cost pass-through in the model when
duration is accounted for and when duration is fixed. To measure pass-through, I simulate a
10 percent reduction in supply costs for all the contracts in my data. For comparison, I provide
three specifications: one in which entry and duration are taken as given, a second in which
entry is endogenous, and a third in which both entry and duration respond to the cost shock.
The results of the counterfactual are reported in Table 11. In the first specification, the
aggregate price falls by exactly 10 percent, as the equilibrium bids in the model are proportional
to supply costs. However, total costs to the buyer fall by only 8.7 percent, as transaction costs
represent a substantial portion of total costs. Thus, these costs that are otherwise hidden may
40
be important to account for when measuring welfare impacts.
In the second specification, I allow the participation of the bidders to respond to the change
in costs. Based on the estimated parameters, lower supply costs results in less entry. Due to
reduced competition, the impact on prices is 14 percent lower (8.6 percent compared to 10
percent). The impact of a reduction in supply costs is not perfectly passed through to prices
because firms adjust their participation decision on the margin.
Likewise, the duration margin also mitigates the pass-through of supply costs to prices.
In the third specification, buyers can adjust duration. In response to lower supply costs, the
average contract duration increases by 6.6 percent. As supply costs increase with duration,
this adjustment partially offsets the reduced supply costs. While allowing for both endogenous
entry and duration to respond, supply prices fall by only 7.7 percent. Thus, the marginal effect
of endogenous duration is to reduce pass-through by 10 percent. In contrast to the previous
counterfactual, here the duration margin provides only a small reduction in total costs.
This counterfactual exercise illustrates that the duration margin can mitigate the pass-
through of costs to prices. It can be important in a welfare analysis, as observed changes to
prices may reflect a number of endogenous levers. Further, prices may only capture a portion
of the total costs, so accounting for transaction costs can be important. In addition, transaction
costs may be affected by a policy change. The changes should be accounted for when evaluating
welfare effects, as well as the equilibrium impacts on duration and price.
7 Conclusion
In this paper, I develop a model of optimal contract duration arising from underlying supply
costs and market transaction costs. I show how latent transaction costs may be recovered from
the duration decision of the buyer. Using a dataset of federal supply contracts, I find that the
costs of going to the market can be a significant portion of total costs for intermediate goods.
The methods developed in this paper may prove useful for welfare analysis, especially in
industries where supply contracts are prevalent. Using counterfactual analyses, I show that
the ability to endogenously adjust contract duration can have meaningful impacts on welfare.
In many settings, the tradeoff presented in this paper may complement other concerns arising
from ex post incentive problems and incomplete contracts. An appropriate model should be
tailored to the industry in question.
The analysis presented here offers, albeit indirectly, one novel prediction regarding the
theory of the firm. Supply contracts lie in between arms-length transactions and vertical inte-
gration. As is known, conditions favorable for long-term contracts are also favorable for vertical
integration, as the end is similar and integration may result in additional benefits. I demon-
strate here that long-term contracts arise when competition is sufficiently low, and also when
competition is very intense. Likewise, vertical integration may be most likely for low levels and
41
high levels of competition. When the industry is moderately competitive, a downstream firm
can realize a large benefit by switching among suppliers and may have the smallest incentive
to integrate upstream.
42
References
ARADILLAS-LÓPEZ, A., A. GANDHI, AND D. QUINT (2013): “Identification and Inference in
Ascending Auctions With Correlated Private Values,” Econometrica, 81, 489–534.
ATALAY, E., A. HORTAÇSU, M. J. LI, AND C. SYVERSON (2017): “How Wide Is the Firm Border?”
Working paper.
BAJARI, P., S. HOUGHTON, AND S. TADELIS (2014): “Bidding for Incomplete Contracts: An
Empirical Analysis of Adaptation Costs,” American Economic Review, 104, 1288–1319.
BAKOS, Y. AND E. BRYNJOLFSSON (1999): “Bundling Information Goods: Pricing, Profits, and
Efficiency,” Management Science, 45, 1613–1630.
BHATTACHARYA, V. (2018): An Empirical Model of R&D Procurement Contests: An Analysis of
the DOD SBIR Program,” Working paper.
CABRAL, L. (2016): “Dynamic Pricing in Customer Markets with Switching Costs,” Review of
Economic Dynamics, 20, 43–62.
CANTILLON, E. AND M. PESENDORFER (2006): “Combination Bidding in Multi-Unit Auctions,”
Manuscript.
CARLTON, D. W. AND B. KEATING (2015): Antitrust, Transaction Costs, and Merger Simulation
with Nonlinear Pricing,” Journal of Law and Economics, 58, 269–289.
COASE, R. H. (1937): “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4, 386.
——— (1960): “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.
DAHLMAN, C. J. (1979): “The Problem of Externality,” The Journal of Law and Economics, 22,
141–162.
DECAROLIS, F. (2014): Awarding Price, Contract Performance, and Bids Screening: Evidence
from Procurement Auctions,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 6, 108–132.
DECAROLIS, F., L. M. GIUFFRIDA, E. IOSSA, V. MOLLISI, AND G. SPAGNOLO (2018): “Bureau-
cratic Competence and Procurement Outcomes,” Working paper.
DUBÉ, J.-P., G. J. HITSCH, AND P. E. ROSSI (2010): “State Dependence and Alternative Expla-
nations for Consumer Inertia,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 41, 417–445.
DYE, R. A. (1985): “Optimal Length of Labor Contracts,” International Economic Review, 26,
251.
43
ELZINGA, K. G. AND D. E. MILLS (1998): “Switching Costs in the Wholesale Distribution of
Cigarettes,” Southern Economic Journal, 65, 282.
GRAY, J. A. (1978): “On Indexation and Contract Length,” The Journal of Political Economy,
1–18.
GREENSTEIN, S. M. (1993): “Did Installed Base Give an Incumbent Any (Measureable) Advan-
tages in Federal Computer Procurement?” The RAND Journal of Economics, 24, 19.
HANDEL, B. R. (2013): Adverse Selection and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets: When
Nudging Hurts,” The American Economic Review, 103, 2643–2682.
HONKA, E. (2014): “Quantifying Search and Switching Costs in the US Auto Insurance Indus-
try,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 45, 847–884.
HU, Y., D. MCADAMS, AND M. SHUM (2013): “Identification of First-Price Auctions with Non-
Separable Unobserved Heterogeneity,” Journal of Econometrics, 174, 186–193.
HYYTINEN, A., S. LUNDBERG, AND O. TOIVANEN (2018): “Design of public procurement auc-
tions: Evidence from cleaning contracts,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 49, 398–426.
JOSKOW, P. L. (1987): “Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical
Evidence from Coal Markets,” The American Economic Review.
KANG, K. AND R. A. MILLER (2017): “Winning by Default: Why Is There So Little Competition
in Government Procurement?” Working paper.
KLEMPERER, P. (1995): “Competition When Consumers Have Switching Costs: An Overview
with Applications to Industrial Organization, Macroeconomics, and International Trade,” The
Review of Economic Studies, 62, 515–539.
KRASNOKUTSKAYA, E. (2011): “Identification and Estimation of Auction Models with Unob-
served Heterogeneity,” The Review of Economic Studies, 78, 293–327.
LAFONTAINE, F. AND M. SLADE (2007): “Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The Evi-
dence,” Journal of Economic Literature, 629–685.
LUCO, F. (2019): “Switching costs and competition in retirement investment,” American Eco-
nomic Journal: Microeconomics, 11, 26–54.
MASTEN, S. E. AND K. J. CROCKER (1985): “Efficient Adaptation in Long-Term Contracts: Take-
or-Pay Provisions for Natural Gas,” The American Economic Review, 1083–1093.
MONTEVERDE, K. AND D. J. TEECE (1982): “Supplier Switching Costs and Vertical Integration
in the Automobile Industry,” The Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 206.
44
PALFREY, T. R. (1983): “Bundling Decisions by a Multiproduct Monopolist with Incomplete
Information,” Econometrica, 51, 463.
QUINT, D. (2015): “Identification in Symmetric English Auctions with Additively Separable
Unobserved Heterogeneity,” Working paper.
RHODES, A. (2014): “Re-Examining the Effects of Switching Costs,” Economic Theory, 57, 161–
194.
ROBERTS, J. W. (2013): “Unobserved Heterogeneity and Reserve Prices in Auctions,” The RAND
Journal of Economics, 44, 712–732.
SALINGER, M. A. (1995): A Graphical Analysis of Bundling,” Journal of Business, 85–98.
STIGLER, G. J. AND J. K. KINDAHL (1970): The Behavior of Industrial Prices, vol. 90, New York,
NY: National Bureau of Economic Research.
WALKER, G. AND D. WEBER (1984): A Transaction Cost Approach to Make-or-Buy Decisions,”
Administrative Science Quarterly, 373–391.
WILLIAMSON, O. E. (1979): “Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Re-
lations,” Journal of Law and Economics, 233–261.
ZHOU, J. (2017): “Competitive Bundling,” Econometrica, 85, 145–172.
45
Appendices
A Model Proofs and Additional Predictions
A.1 Proof of Propositions 1 and 2
By assumption, an interior solution exists. Let the set of possible contracts be order in increasing
duration: T = {1, ..., R, S, T, ...}. At an interior solution S, it must be that
P (R) P (S)
δ
P
R
k=1
β
k1
δ
P
S
k=1
β
k1
!
(15)
P (T) P (S) +
δ
P
S
k=1
β
k1
δ
P
T
k=1
β
k1
!
. (16)
These are obtained by simple rearrangements of equation (4). Because β (0, 1] and R S
T , both terms in parentheses are positive. Therefore, the function P is locally increasing the
duration of the contract, i.e., P (S) P (T ).
Further, an increase in δ decreases the right-hand side of equation (15), so that the in-
equality remains satisfied. An increase in δ increases the right-hand side of equation (16). No
increase in δ could make the shorter contract R preferred to S, but a large enough increase in
δ will flip the inequality in (16), and the longer contract T will be preferred to S. QED.
A.2 Additional Predictions from Model
Recall the decision rule for the buyer from the illustrative example. The buyer will choose a
long-term contract if and only if
E[˜c
2:N
] E[c
2:N
] <
δ
2
(17)
This simple decision rule generates a number of comparative statics. I discuss two of these in
the main text, and I present additional ones here.
Remark 3 Higher marginal costs lead to shorter contracts.
Higher marginal costs increase the left-hand side of equation (17). This increases the cost of
long-term contracts relative to the savings in transaction costs, which shifts buyers to long-term
contracts at the margin. Similarly, this an increase in transaction costs affects the right-hand
side only and leads to longer contracts.
Remark 4 The optimal duration is increasing with autocorrelation in supply costs.
46
This prediction is intuitive. As the autocorrelation in marginal costs increases, there is less of a
benefit from switching suppliers, and longer-term contracts are preferred. Suppose that d is a
cost process with lower autocorrelation than c, but the same per-period marginal distribution,
i.e. E[d
2:N
] = E[c
2:N
]. Let
˜
d denote the average cost across two periods. Then it follows that,
for N > 3,
E[
˜
d
2:N
] > E[˜c
2:N
]
= E[
˜
d
2:N
] E[d
2:N
] > E[˜c
2:N
] E[c
2:N
].
The marginal cost of long-term contracts is decreasing with the autocorrelation of the cost
process. With greater autocorrelation, long-term contracts are preferred.
Remark 5 The optimal duration is decreasing in the variance of costs across suppliers, provided
there is sufficient competition (N > 3).
For a simple case, consider location-scale transformations of c, such that d = a + bc and E[d] =
E[c]. Under the marginal cost structure d, a longer contract is chosen if
b · (E[˜c
2:N
] E[c
2:N
]) <
δ
2
.
As b increases, shorter contracts become more desirable.
Remark 6 When costs are bounded from below, the optimal duration is U-shaped in the vari-
ance in costs, provided there is sufficient competition (N > 3).
From a starting point of zero variance across suppliers, increasing the variance of marginal
costs leads to shorter contracts, as there is more to gain from selecting the low-cost supplier
in each period. This holds for the buyer-optimal contract as long as there are more than three
suppliers, in which case the expected second-order statistic falls below the median. When costs
are bounded from below, eventually both E[˜c
2:N
] and E[c
2:N
] approach zero, and the cost of
a longer duration falls with respect to transaction costs. After a certain threshold, contract
duration increases.
This occurs because the expected average price and expected per-period price approach
the lower bound. Let c denote per-period marginal costs with a lower bound at 0, and let σ
represent its standard deviation. Then, when N > 3,
lim
σ→∞
E[˜c
2:N
] = lim
σ→∞
E[c
2:N
] = 0.
As E[˜c
2:N
] E[c
2:N
] 0, long-term contracts are optimal in the limit. This effect tends to
dominate as N gets large, as more draws brings the minimum price closer to the lower bound.
47
Figure 6: Increased Variance in Cost
Baseline
Increased Variance
δ
2
= 0.1
0.00
0.05
0.10
5 10 15 20 25 30
Number of Suppliers
Change in Expected Cost
Notes: The blue line shows the marginal cost to the buyer of a two-period contract
relative to one-period contracts and is equivalent to the blue line in Figure 1. The red
line shows the marginal cost of a longer contract when the costs are draw from the
same distributional family (the beta distribution) with 11 percent greater variance.
This tradeoff is illustrated in Figure 6. The blue line displays the baseline marginal cost
of longer contracts, corresponding to the blue line in panel (b) of Figure 1 in the main text.
Costs drawn from a beta distribution with shape parameters (0.5, 0.5). The red line displays
the change in marginal costs when variance of the cost distribution increases by 11 percent,
corresponding to a beta distributions with shape parameters (0.4, 0.4).
For N < 12, greater variance increases the cost of long-term contracts, reflecting the intu-
ition of Remark 5. When N 13, the winning supplier’s price is close enough to the lower
bound to reduce the cost, reflecting the prediction of Remark 6. Thus, the figure illustrates
how an increase in variance leads to shorter contracts when competition is lower and longer
contracts when competition is intense.
48
B Efficiency and Allocation of Rights
In this section, I explore the relationship between optimal and efficient contract duration. It
should be noted that the analysis here is not restricted to the special case of the duration-
setting problem, rather, any transaction characteristic that has a “scale” effect (as duration does
on transaction costs) can be related to this framework. One of the natural extensions is to
bundling, where T is the size of a bundle (determined by the buyer or seller) and δ is the
transaction cost for the bundle.
B.1 A Framework Relating Optimal and Efficient Contract Duration
In contrast to the buyer, whose problem was presented in Section 2, the social planner’s concern
is minimizing expected costs.
37
Let C denote the ex ante expected cost conditional on (T, x, m),
so that C(T, x, m) =
P
N
n=1
(E[C(n, T, x, m)]· Pr(N = n|T, x, m)).
For ease of exposition, assume that T is continuous and β = 1. Thus, the ex ante efficient
˜
T
contract is given by
˜
T = arg min
T T
C(T, x, m) +
δ
T
(18)
with the first-order condition
dC(T, x, m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
=
δ
˜
T
2
. (19)
In general,
d
C(T,x,m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
6=
dP (T,x,m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
, which will result in an inefficiency when the
contract is determined by the buyer. As long as interior solutions exist (see Proposition 9), we
have the result that the efficient contract
˜
T will be longer than the buyer-optimal contract T
when
dC(T,x,m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
<
dP (T,x,m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
Defining the expected seller surplus as E[π(T, x, m)] = P (T, x, m) C(T, x, m)], we have
the following result:
Proposition 8. When interior solutions to the buyer’s problem and the social planner’s problem
exist, the efficient contract will be longer than the equilibrium (buyer-optimal) contract if and only
if the expected seller surplus is increasing at
˜
T :
˜
T > T
dP (T, x, m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
dC(T, x, m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
> 0
dE[π(T, x, m)]
dT
|
T =
˜
T
> 0
The existence of interior solutions depends on the concavity of the expected price function.
37
In this setting, I assume the social planner is limited by information constraints; in this setting the social planner
cannot observe the private information about sellers’ costs. This reflects the idea that the mechanism (and the asso-
ciated transaction costs) are important to the truthful revelation of information. A third party with full information
would solve a different problem, awarding the contract to the lowest-cost seller at every instant and switching when
the net savings outweigh the transaction cost.
49
Proposition 9. Interior solutions to the buyer’s problem and social planner’s problem exist as long
as the first-order conditions can be satisfied and P (T, x, m) and C(T, x, m) are not too concave.
In particular,
d
2
P (T,x,m)
dT
2
|
T =T
>
2
T
P (T,x,m)
dT
|
T =T
and
d
2
C(T,x,m)
dT
2
|
T =
˜
T
>
2
˜
T
C(T,x,m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
.
These are the second-order conditions to ensure that first-order conditions achieve a minimum.
B.2 Numerical Illustration
To illustrate the difference in contracts, we replicate the illustrative example from section 2.2.
The social planner’s problem is similar to the buyers problem, except that the social planner
will choose a long-term contract if
E[˜c
1:N
] E[c
1:N
] <
δ
2
.
Thus, the social planner’s decision depends on the first-order statistic of cost draws, rather than
the second-order statistic that generates the expected price. For N > 3, these order statistics
have similar qualitative behavior, so the comparative static predictions follow for the efficient
case. However, the efficient contract will not necessarily coincide with the buyer-optimal con-
tract, raising the question of the allocation of rights to non-price terms of the transaction.
Figure 7 provides a comparison of the buyer-optimal and the efficient contract. Panel (a)
displays the marginal impact on the price to the buyer of a longer contract with a blue line. The
orange line displays the marginal impact on supply costs. Once N is large enough (N > 5 in the
example), longer contracts have a greater marginal effect on price than cost. This is intuitive,
as the first-order statistic approaches the lower bound faster than the second-order statistic.
Panel (b) plots the efficient contract with an orange dashed line. It has similar qualitative
features to the buyer-optimal contract, displaying the inverse U shape. The efficient and buyer-
optimal contract coincide only when N {6, 7}. When N = 4, the buyer would choose a
long-term contract when the short-term contract is efficient, and when N 8, ..., 21 the buyer
would choose a short-term contract when a long-term contract is efficient. Thus, the buyer-
optimal contract may be longer or shorter than the efficient contract. Information rents from
private costs drive a wedge between the buyer-optimal contract and the efficient contract.
Reflecting Proposition 8, the buyer-optimal contract is (weakly) shorter than the efficient
contract when seller surplus is increasing with the longer contract, i.e., when the blue line is
above the orange line in panel (a).
B.3 Allocation of Term-Setting Rights
Given the general model, we can identify settings in which inefficiency arising from market
power over contract length may be of first-order importance. In this section, I provide some in-
tuition and a heuristic guide to the assignment of term-setting rights to limit such inefficiencies.
50
Figure 7: Comparing Buyer-Optimal and Efficient Contracts
(a) The Marginal Costs of Longer Contracts
Change in Price
Change in Cost
δ
2
= 0.1
0.00
0.05
0.10
5 10 15 20 25 30
Number of Suppliers
Change in Expected Cost
(b) Efficient versus Optimal Contracts
N=6
N=22
N=4
N=8
1
2
5 10 15 20 25 30
Number of Suppliers
Efficient Duration
Notes: The figure shows the relationship between competition, the marginal costs of
longer contracts, and the effect on buyer-optimal and efficient durations. The blue
line in panel (a) shows the marginal cost to the buyer of a two-period contract and
is equivalent to the blue line in Figure 1. The orange line shows the increase in
marginal social costs of a longer contract. The dash line reflects a transaction cost of
0.20 amortized over two periods. For values of N where the blue line is above the
dashed line, N {6, ..., 21}, the buyer would prefer to issue one-period contracts,
as the increase in price is greater than the savings in transaction costs. This range
does not coincide with the efficient contract, which is plotted with the orange dashed
line in panel (b). One-period contracts are efficient for N {4, .., 7}. The buyer will
select the efficient contract in this example only if N {6, 7}.
The buyer’s problem can be written in the following form:
min
T
P (T, x, m) C(T, x, m) + C(T, x, m) +
δ
T
= min
T
E[π(T, x, m)] + C(T, x, m) +
δ
T
Notice that when
dE[π(T,x,m)]
dT
= 0, this problem is equivalent to the social planner’s problem.
Therefore, when the buyer sets the duration of the contract, these contracts will be efficient
51
when the seller surplus does not change with the length of the contract. The more sensitive
buyer surplus is to the duration of the contract, the greater the potential for inefficiency.
What about assigning contract term-setting power along with the transaction costs to the
sellers? Sellers solve the problem:
max
T
P (T, x, m) C(T, x, m)
δ
T
= min
T
P (T, x, m) + C(T, x, m) +
δ
T
Sellers solve the social planner problem when
dP (T,x,m)
dT
= 0. Therefore, if price is not sen-
sitive to contract duration, it is efficient to let the sellers determine the length of the contract.
38
If either price or buyer surplus changes with the duration of the contract, there is potential
for inefficiency arising from market power. A simple heuristic to mitigate efficiency loss is to let
sellers determine contract duration when the duration affects price more than buyer surplus,
and to let buyers determine contract duration otherwise.
These heuristics, combined with Proposition 8, provide insight into which settings may
allow for substantive inefficiencies and whether the efficient contract is longer or shorter. Below,
I provide a simple example to illustrate how changing the allocation of rights over non-price
terms, such as duration, may lead to vastly different outcomes.
Example: Markup Pricing Suppose sellers in equilibrium follow a simple markup pricing rule,
P = µC. Then the buyer’s problem is
min
T
µC(T, x, m) +
δ
T
and the seller’s problem is
min
T
(1 µ)C(T, x, m) +
δ
T
As µ 1 in equilibrium, the seller’s problem reverses the sign that expected costs enter
in the objective function. By increasing costs, sellers increase total profits. In this setting,
the buyer should determine the duration. The greater the markup, the more that the
equilibrium contract will diverge from the efficient contract.
B.4 Achieving Efficiency with a Tax
The efficient contract can be achieved with a per-transaction tax (or subsidy) when either side
of the transaction holds the term-setting rights. When the buyer determines the length of the
38
Sellers have an equivalent rule to Proposition 8: t
S
>
˜
T
dP (T ,x,m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
> 0. This means that either 1)
t
S
˜
T t, 2) t
˜
T t
S
, or 3) t
S
˜
T t
˜
T . The case where both the buyer-optimal and seller-optimal
contract are shorter than the efficient contract is ruled out by the fact that per-period costs must be increasing at
the efficient contract for an interior solution.
52
contract, the efficient per-transaction tax τ
B
solves
τ
B
=
˜
T
2
dE[π(T, x, m)]
dT
|
T =
˜
T
This tax equates the buyer’s problem with the social planner’s problem. Note below how
the tax causes the externality on the seller to drop out at the efficient contract.
˜
T = arg min
T
E[π(T, x, m)] + C(T, x, m) +
δ + τ
B
T
= arg min
T
E[π(T, x, m)] +
τ
B
T
+ C(T, x, m) +
δ
T
= arg min
T
C(T, x, m) +
δ
T
Analogously, the efficient tax on the seller (when the seller has term-setting rights) is given
by
τ
S
=
˜
T
2
dP (T, x, m)
dT
|
T =
˜
T
In general, τ
S
6= τ
B
. A policymaker has a choice between two efficient taxes, with different
effects on tax revenue.
53
C Dataset Details
C.1 Sample Construction
To construct this dataset, I combined detailed location, price, and vendor information main-
tained in the Federal Procurement Data System (FPDS)
39
with contract-specific documents
downloaded from the Federal Business Opportunities (FedBizOpps) website. By law, the FPDS
keeps public records of all contracts for the U.S. federal government. The FedBizOpps website
is the most common posting location for competitive contracts, which must be posted publicly.
From October 2003 through May 2017, I identified 11,210 unique solicitations in the FPDS data
and 7,984 unique solicitations in the FedBizOpps data that matched either PSC S201 (“House-
keeping: Custodial Janitorial”) or principal NAICS code 561720 (“Janitorial Services”). I was
able to merge 4,119 of these contracts. Unique contracts were identified in FPDS from the
variables IDVPIID and PIID.
From the solicitations found in both systems, I selected competitive, non-zero value con-
tracts in the United States that had documents with relevant cost information (i.e., square
footage).
40
I obtained the relevant contract documents (request for proposal, cleaning fre-
quency charts, maps, etc.), and constructed detailed contract information directly from the
documents. The resulting 1,427 contracts were further processed by hand to construct key
variables, including the square footage of the site to be cleaned, the frequency of service,
41
and
the facility type. Contracts that were restricted to economically disadvantaged businesses were
removed from the sample. After identifying contracts for regular cleaning service, I restricted
the sample to contracts that received more than one bid and had an annual price of less than
$1 million. Table 12 summarizes the construction of the dataset.
I matched the contract-specific dataset with auxiliary datasets of (1) government contract-
ing expenditures at the same location in related products and (2) local labor market conditions.
Local labor market conditions include county-level unemployment from the Local Area Unem-
ployment Statistics and the number of NAICS-code level establishments in the same 3-digit ZIP
code from the County Business Patterns data.
Because contract characteristics (square footage and cleaning frequency) are important con-
trol variables, I am unable to construct a larger dataset using the FPDS data alone. It also proved
very difficult to identify repeat contracts for the same facility in the data, for which it might be
reasonable to impute characteristics without observing the contract. Two reasons made this
challenging. First, ZIP codes change frequently, so it is difficult to link contracts over time (see
the set of identified follow-on contracts in Section 5.4). Second, these contracts last for several
years, so there are only a handful of contracts for each facility that hypothetically exist in the
39
These data were obtained from USASpending.gov.
40
The candidate solicitations were identified with a computational text analysis of documents from all matched
contracts.
41
Cleaning frequency is encoded as the maximum required weekly frequency.
54
Table 12: Construction of Sample
Criterion Observations Portion
(1) FedBizOpps Solicitation IDs 7,984
(2) FPDS Solicitation IDs 11,210
Matched (1) and (2) 4,119
(3) In United States 3,818 0.93
(4) Competitive Procurement 3,584 0.94
(5) Non-Zero FPDS Value 4,064 0.99
(6) Square Footage Indicators 1,654 0.40
Intersection of (3)-(6) 1,427 0.35
(7) US, Excluding Territories 1,409 0.99
(8) Regular Cleaning Service 1,405 0.98
(9) Measurable Square Footage 1,301 0.91
(10) No Economic Disadvantage Preference 1,289 0.90
(11) Single Auction, More Than 1 Bid 1,339 0.94
(12) Annual Price Less Than $1,000,000 1,338 0.94
Estimation Sample
Intersection of (7)-(12) 1,046 0.73
Notes: The table describes the construction of the estimation sample from two data sources for facility
cleaning contracts for the U.S. federal government. The relevant range is from October 1, 2003 through
May 1, 2017 for the Federal Procurement Data System and though February 3, 2017 for FedBizOpps.
After cleaning identification variables, 4,119 of the solicitations were matched. Of these, 1,046 met
the criteria needed for analysis, including the availability of square footage data, which is a key cost
indicator, non-zero value, and receiving more than one bid from the solicitation.
FPDS. A longer panel and supplemental facility identifiers would facilitate the construction of
a larger dataset.
55
C.2 Count of Sites by Location Type and Government Agency
Table 13: Count of Sites by Contracting Agency
Agency Count Percent
Defense 389 37.2
Agriculture 347 33.2
Veterans Affairs 80 7.7
Commerce 78 7.5
Homeland Security 45 4.3
Interior 43 4.1
GSA 40 3.8
Energy 5 0.5
Labor 5 0.5
Transportation 4 0.4
EPA 2 0.2
State 2 0.2
National Archives 2 0.2
CNCS 1 0.1
Health And Human Services 1 0.1
OPIC 1 0.1
Railroad Retirement Board 1 0.1
Total 1,046 100.0
Notes: The table lists the count of contracts in the estimation sample by gov-
ernment department or agency.
56
Table 14: Count of Contracts by Location Type
Category Sub-Category Count
Office (424)
Office 221
Recruiting Office 203
Field Office (270)
Ranger District Office 171
Field Office 46
Ranger Station 43
Work Center 7
Reserve Fleet 3
Research (111)
Weather Station 43
Laboratory 28
Research Center 28
Plant Materials Center 12
Medical (61)
Clinic 36
Medical Center 25
Services (59)
Service Center 38
Vet Center 21
Visitors (41)
Recreation Area 18
Cemetery 9
Visitor Center 7
Restroom 4
Museum 3
Airport (30)
Airport 30
Technical (19)
Power Plant 14
Surveillance Center 4
Data Center 1
Accommodations (18)
Housing 14
Dormitories 4
Industrial (13)
Equipment Center 6
Warehouse 6
Gym 2
Total 1,046
Notes: The table lists the count of contracts in the estimation sample by facility
type. Types were hand-coded after reading the contract documents.
57
C.3 Summary Statistics by Department
Table 15: Summary Statistics by Department
Department Duration Price Square Footage Count
Mean S.D. Mean Mean
Defense 4.1 1.3 38,782 27,517 389
Agriculture 3.9 1.2 18,685 13,285 347
Veterans Affairs 4.6 1.2 61,040 24,647 80
Commerce 4.7 0.8 15,846 9,578 78
Homeland Security 4.8 0.4 93,738 21,746 45
Interior 4.1 1.4 28,746 15,709 43
GSA 4.6 1.1 222,045 144,749 40
Other 4.5 1.1 160,972 58,578 24
Notes: The table displays summary statistics for the contract characteristics of the estimation sample grouped
by federal department. The mean and standard deviation for contract duration are provided, along with the
mean annual price and the mean square footage. The final column reports the count of contracts in each
department.
58
C.4 Contract Documents
The following page is an example first page from a building cleaning service contract. The
subsequent pages contain an example description of the required services and their respective
frequencies.
59
COMMERCIAL ITEMS SOL NO.: AG-9A63-S-10-0004
PROJ NAME: Janitorial Services
UNIT Georgetown Ranger District
8
CONTRACT DOCUMENTS, EXHIBITS OR ATTACHMENTS
C.1 SCOPE OF CONTRACT
Description of Work: The intent of this contract is to secure services (inclusive of supplies) for normal
custodial (janitorial) and routine maintenance service at the Georgetown Ranger District of the Eldorado
National Forest.
2 Project Location & Description
Location: The project is located on the Georgetown Ranger District, 7600 Wentworth Springs Road,
Georgetown, CA 95634.
Description: The headquarters office of the Georgetown Ranger District is located at 7600 Wentworth
Springs Road, Georgetown, California. Winter working hours are 6:00 a.m. through 5:30 p.m. Monday
through Friday from November through May. Summer hours are 7:00 a.m. through 6:00 p.m. Sunday
through Saturday.
The office building contains approximately 6,376 gross square feet of space. The office is carpeted
throughout, expect for restrooms and front reception area. There are 6 restrooms in the building.
Any prospective contractor desiring an explanation or interpretation of the solicitation, drawings,
specifications, etc., must request it in writing from the Contracting Officer soon enough to allow a reply to
reach all prospective contractors before the solicitation closing date. Oral explanations or instructions given
before the award of a contract will not be binding.
3 Estimated Start Date & Contract Time
Start: January 1, 2010
Time: 9 Months
4 Cleaning Schedule
Work Days and Hours. Work shall be performed during Monday through Friday, provided that no work is
performed between 7 a.m. and 4:30 p.m. on normal Federal workdays. Regularly scheduled twice weekly
work will not be on consecutive days. The contractor may work in the building on weekends and Federal
holidays without restrictions to hours.
Quarterly cleaning items will be performed the first week (preferably on Friday) of December, March, June,
and September. Annual cleaning shall be performed during the first 2 weeks of May.
5 Licenses and Insurance
Contractor shall provide proof of Workman’s Compensation. If the contractor is working alone, with no
employees, no Workman’s Compensation is required.
.
6 Contractor-Furnished Materials and Services
6-1. The Contractor shall provide everything--including, but not limited to, all equipment, supplies (listed
below), transportation, labor, and supervision--necessary to complete the project, except for that which the
contract clearly states is to be furnished by the Government.
60
18. TECHNICAL SPECIFICATIONS
The janitorial services shall be performed in accordance with the following specifications
at the frequencies prescribed.
1. Services Performed Daily - Bid Item #0001
a. Restrooms
Clean and sanitize all surfaces including sinks, counters, toilet bowls, toilet
seats, urinals, etc.
Clean and sanitize tile walls adjacent to and behind urinals and water closets.
Clean and sanitize sanitary napkin receptacles and replace liners.
Sweep, mop and sanitize tile floors.
Clean and polish mirrors, dispensers and chrome fixtures
Empty, clean and sanitize all wastebaskets.
Spot clean all other surfaces and dust horizontal surfaces including tops of
partitions and mirrors.
Re-stock restroom supplies.
b. Front Foyer and Doors
Wash inside and outside of all glass surfaces on entrance doors. Remove dust
and soil from metal frames surrounding entrance glass doors.
Vacuum rugs.
Sweep and mop tile floors and clean baseboards.
c. Reception Area
Vacuum all reception carpeted areas and rugs including edges.
Clean and polish all counter surfaces.
d. Drinking Fountains
Clean and sanitize drinking fountains.
e. Breakroom Waste Receptacles
Empty all waste receptacles, wash if needed with a sanitizing cleaner.
2. Services Performed Weekly – Bid Item #0002
a. Waste Receptacles
Empty all waste receptacles unless needed more frequently. Wash if needed
with a sanitizing cleaner. Change liners only if needed.
b. Breakroom
Sweep and mop, use a cleaner that doesn’t require rinsing and is a sanitizer
and will not damage the wax. Mop under table, chairs, coffeemaker cabinet,
trash can and wheeled carts.
Clean Formica countertops.
61
Spot clean walls and doors.
c. Back Door Foyers
Sweep and mop, use a cleaner that doesn’t require rinsing and is a sanitizer
and will not damage the wad. Vacuum rug and clean baseboards.
Spot clean walls and doors.
d. Hallways
Vacuum all carpeted areas, including wall edges.
Spot clean anytime a stain or soiled area needs cleaning.
Tile floors sweep and mop, use a cleaner that doesn’t require rinsing and is a
sanitizer and will not damage the wax.
Spot clean walls, doors and partitions that appears to be soiled.
e. Outdoor Waste Receptacles
Empty all outdoor waste receptacles and ash trays at the front entrance and
two back entrances. Wash if needed with a sanitizing cleaner. Change liners
if needed.
f. Conference Room
Clean and polish conference room tables.
Vacuum all carpeted areas, including wall edges and around the edges of all
furniture which is not easily moveable, this includes under desks, tables,
chairs etc. All light weight furniture must be moved and vacuumed under.
All electrical cords must be picked up and vacuumed under.
Spot clean anytime a stain or soiled area needs cleaning.
Vacuum chalk dust out of chalk tray. Wash chalkboard only if it has been
erased by the Forest Service.
g. Copy Machine and Mail room area
Vacuum all carpeted areas, including wall edges and around the edges of all
furniture which is not easily moveable, this includes under desks, tables,
chairs etc. All light weight furniture must be moved and vacuumed under.
All electrical cords must be picked up and vacuumed under.
Spot clean anytime a stain or soiled area needs cleaning.
Clean and polish table and counter tops.
3. Services Performed Monthly - Bid Item #0003
a. Dusting
Dust below a 5 foot level. Dust all horizontal and vertical surfaces including
but not limited to furniture, baseboards, wood molding, windowsills,
bookcases, ledges, signs, wall hangings, photographs, fire alarm boxes,
exhibits, top edge of privacy partitions, excluding desktops and computers.
b. Offices
Vacuum all carpeted areas, including wall edges and around the edges of all
furniture which is not easily moveable, this includes under desks, tables,
62
chairs etc. All light weight furniture must be moved and vacuumed under.
All electrical cords must be picked up and vacuumed under.
Spot clean anytime a stain or soiled area needs cleaning.
Tile floors sweep and mop, use a cleaner that doesn’t require rinsing and is a
sanitizer and will not damage the wax.
c. Outside Foyer and Adjacent Areas
Sweep outside area around all outside doors and adjacent area.
Pick up any trash laying within 100 feet on the outside of the office building
and parking area. This includes all the bushes and trees.
4. Services Performed Annually - - Bid Item #0004
a. Dusting above 5 feet
All horizontal and vertical dust catching surfaces shall be kept free of obvious
dust, dirt, and cobwebs. Dust furniture in all offices above the 5 foot level,
including, but not limited to tops of high bookcases and top edge of privacy
partitions.
b. Windows
Clean all windows and screens inside and outside of building, with an
appropriate glass cleaner. Removing screens on windows that have screens
for cleaning.
c. Blinds
Dust, clean and/or vacuum all window blinds. Vinyl blinds may require a
liquid cleaner and blinds with fabric may require vacuuming. Clean in
accordance with manufacturer’s recommendations by type of fabric or
material.
d. Chairs
Vacuum all upholstered chairs.
Clean all vinyl covered chairs with an appropriate cleaner for vinyl.
Clean chair legs and/or pedestal bases on all the chairs in the office.
Wood chairs use an oil, such as lemon oil.
e. Door and Door Frames
Clean with appropriate wood/metal cleaner and apply a good penetrating oil to
the wood doors.
63
D Measurement Error in FPDS
Though the FPDS data are broadly appealing for research, there is measurement error in the
data. Examining the stream of entries under each contract suggests that user input error can
be significant. For example, the initial entry for the contract may report the completion date to
be equal to the start date of the contract, even though a later entry shows that the contract was
for a longer period. Likewise, there are inconsistencies in how the dollar values of the contract
are reported across entries. As most contracts have multiple entries and multiple indicators of
duration and value within each entry, different assumptions about data quality could lead to
widely different measures of price. As I obtained high-quality measures of price and duration
from a second data source, FedBizOpps, I was able to cross-validate the data and construct
preferred measures from the FPDS.
D.1 Cross-Validating Initial Entries in FPDS with Realized Contracts
Obtaining a quality measure of initial contract value is important. In this paper, I examine how
this value shifts with contract duration. As another example, recent papers study cost overruns,
or charges over and above the initial contract value (see, e.g., Decarolis et al., 2018). In my
sample, I have found the initial measures of total contract value taking directly from the FPDS
to be unreliable. This is likely due to entry error, as FPDS data are not automatically generated
directly from the signed contracts.
To account for this potential measurement error, I obtained a sample of 75 realized contracts
from FedBizOpps that had finalized terms for price, duration, and total contract value. By
comparing the terms on the contract to what is reported in FPDS, I am able to to get a sense for
the degree of measurement error.
Each entry in FPDS has three measures of value: dollars obligated, base and exercised op-
tions value, and base and all options value. The first corresponds to the accounting amount
owed at the time of the action, the second should correspond to the total value of future pay-
ments for the options that have been exercised, and the third should correspond to the full
value of all options on the contract. The third measure is the greatest of the three (except for
additional input error), so, as a conservative measure, I consider this the initial reported value
in FPDS.
42
Using the other two measures exacerbates the measurement error I show below.
Comparing the initial entries to actual contract terms shows that the initial contract value
reported in FPDS does not accurately measure the initial contract value. Figure 8 shows the
initial reported contract value in FPDS plotted against the actual initial value obtained directly
from the contract. The plot is in log terms, and the 45-degree red line indicates an exact corre-
spondence between the two values. Points lying below the red line indicate underreporting. 45
42
Instructions from the FPDS user manual corresponding to this variable: “Enter the mutually agreed upon total
contract or order value including all options (if any). For modifications, this is the change (positive or negative, if
any) in the mutually agreed upon total contract value.” https://fpds.gov/wiki/index.php/FPDS-NG_User_Manual
64
Figure 8: Measurement Error in FPDS Initial Entries
6 8 10 12 14 16
Log Contract Value: FPDS Initial Entry
8 10 12 14 16
Log Contract Value: Actual
Notes: Figure displays the (log) contract value according to the initial entry in the Federal Procurement Data
System (FPDS) versus the actual initial (log) contract value. The actual initial contract value was obtained for
a sample of 75 completed contracts from the analysis sample. Roughly three-quarters of the points lie below
the 45-degree line (plotted in red), which indicates systematic underreporting in the FPDS relative to the true
contract value. The initial measure from the FPDS corresponds to “Base And All Options Value”, which is the
largest of the three measures reported in each FPDS entry.
of the 75 contracts show underreporting in the initial entry in the FPDS. The median (mean)
difference is -1.099 log points, corresponding to a 67 percent difference.
Examining each of the 75 contracts shows that measurement error arises from a variety of
inconsistencies in how data are entered into FPDS. One error that occurs with some frequency
is that the user enters only the contract value for that fiscal year, rather than the full value of
the contract. In the sample of 75 contracts, the median duration is 3 years, so applying this
error across all the contracts would result underreporting of 67 percent as above. Because the
typical building cleaning contract is 3 to 4 times longer that the average service contract, this
error may be of more importance for this category relative to other service contracts; however,
other forms of entry error could also lead to systematic underreporting.
Another common entry error is that the user enters the amount of dollars obligated across
all three of the variables for contract value, rather than indicating the total value of the contract
using base and all options value. Table 16 provides an example of the first five entries in FPDS
corresponding to a single contract. The entry for the total value is equivalent to the dollars
obligated in the first entry ($10,740), as well as in all following entries. According to the posting
on FedBizOpps on January 26, 2010, the total value of the five-year contract (“Contract Award
Dollar Amount”) was $54,300. This is equal to the sum of dollars obligated across all 13 entries
in FPDS for the contract. The amounts entered in FPDS in these cases are best interpreted as
accounting measures for past and current payments, rather than future obligations that capture
65
Table 16: Entries in FPDS for an Example Contract
modnumber reasonformodification effectivedate ultimatecompletiondate dollarsobligated baseandalloptionsvalue
0 1/1/2010 12/31/2014 10740 10740
1 C: FUNDING ONLY ACTION 12/8/2010 12/8/2010 2700 2700
2 M: OTHER ADMINISTRATIVE ACTION 4/14/2011 9/30/2011 900 900
3 C: FUNDING ONLY ACTION 5/6/2011 9/30/2011 4500 4500
4 C: FUNDING ONLY ACTION 10/18/2011 3/31/2012 5415 5415
... ... ... ... ... ...
Notes: Table displays the first five entries in FPDS corresponding to contract PIID AG0276P100005. This contract
illustrates a typical entry mistake in FPDS, where the user enters the same amount for dollars obligated and the total
value of the contract (base and all options value). On the FedBizOpps website, a posting dated January 26, 2010
states the total value of the five-year contract (“Contract Award Dollar Amount”) of $54,300. The total of dollars
obligated across all 13 entries in FPDS is equal to this value.
total contract value.
D.2 Constructing Accurate Measures of Contract Value
Though the initial entry is not reliable for estimating the total contract value, additional mea-
sures can be obtained from the FPDS that perform well. For example, if the same value of
dollars obligated are reported in consecutive years, then that value likely represents the annual
price of the contract. In supplemental work, I detail the steps to cross-check the data and dif-
ferent candidate measures for price and duration. These comparisons result in the following
recommendations:
Duration The maximum observed date in the contract, minus the start date in the first entry
within a contract.
Price The price is the value of obligated dollars if it is the same (or within 10 percent) in consecu-
tive years. If this is not observable, use the maximum value of the three (summed) measures
of dollar amounts for the total value of the contract. Divide this by the duration measure
above to obtain the price.
Any missing values of price or duration in the FedBizOpps data are imputed with the above
values constructed from FPDS. Researchers interested working with the FPDS data may contact
the author for additional details about the measurement error in the FPDS data and the accu-
racy of variables constructed under alternative assumptions. Though these measures are not
completely free from measurement error, the cross-validation exercise suggests that they are
centered on the true value, as opposed to being systematically underreported. These measures
are most applicable to fixed-price contracts, where the ex post payments are not subject to the
same degree of uncertainty as, for example, cost-plus contracts.
66
Figure 9: Cost Overruns or Measurement Error?
(a) Total Obligated vs. Actual Contract Value
8 10 12 14 16
Log Total Obligated
8 10 12 14 16
Log Contract Value: Actual
(b) Total Obligated vs. FPDS Initial Value
6 8 10 12 14 16
Log Total Obligated
6 8 10 12 14 16
Log Contract Value: FPDS Initial Entry
Notes: Figure displays the (log) total payments on a contract (total obligated) vs. two different measures
of initial contract value. Total payments are calculated from summing up dollars obligated across entries
in the FPDS. Panel (a) compares total payments to the actual value obtained for a sample of 75 completed
contracts. Panel (b) compares total payments to the initial reported contract value in the FPDS for the same
sample. Points lying above the 45-degree line (plotted in red) correspond to inferred cost overruns. The
median implied overrun in panel (a) is 0. The median implied overrun in panel (b) is 0.242 log points, or 27
percent. The fact that many of the points (61 percent) lie above the 45-degree line in panel (b) arises from
the measurement error in the initial FPDS entry, which is captured in Figure 8.
D.3 Is There Evidence of Cost Overruns?
Examining the initial contract value from a sample of contracts provides further evidence that
ex post incentive concerns may not be first-order for building cleaning services. One indicator
of ex post incentive problems is the presence of cost overruns, or payments above and beyond
the initially agreed-upon amount.
By calculating the total amount paid on an individual contract and comparing it to the total
amount, we can examine whether the buyer (the government) ends up paying more in cost
overruns. The sample of 75 contracts used to benchmark these figures all finished before the
end of the data, so the total amounts reflect the full time series of payments.
Figure 9 examines cost overruns by plotting the (log) total amount obligated on the contract
against measures of the initial value of the contract. The red 45-degree line indicates exact
correspondence between the initial value and the total payments. Panel (a) compares the total
payments to the actual initial value of the contract. The total payments follow the initial value
of the payments quite closely. A regression of (log) total obligated on (log) initial contract value
returns a coefficient of 0.99. The median cost overrun in the sample, defined as the difference
between the two logged values, is zero.
Panel (b) compares the total payments to the total value according to the initial entry in
FPDS. The median implied overrun is 0.242 log points, or 27 percent. The majority of points
67
(61 percent) lie above the 45-degree line, suggesting a substantial degree of cost overruns.
Likewise, the 75 percentile of implied overruns is 1.27 log points, compared to only 0.05 log
points when using the actual initial value in panel (a). The fact that this panel suggest cost
overruns is a direct result of measurement error in the initial entry in FPDS. The underreporting
showing in Figure 8 translates to implied cost overruns. Measurement error is further captured
by a regression of (log) total obligated on (log) contract value according to the initial entry in
FPDS. The coefficient estimate is only 0.57, compared to 0.99 when a more accurate measure
of initial value is used.
Thus, a comparison of payments made to actual initial contract value demonstrates that cost
overruns are not a significant concern for this product category (building cleaning services with
an annual price less than $1 million). This provides suggestive evidence that ex post incentive
concerns are not first-order in this market.
68
E Identification Proofs
E.1 Some Lemmas
To demonstrate the following proofs, it will be useful to first introduce several lemmas.
Lemma 1. For symmetric auctions with independent private values, E[b
1:N
] = E[c
2:N
].
This is a standard result and can be obtained directly by taking the expectation given the
equilibrium bid function. I omit the proof here.
Lemma 2. min b
1:N
= E[c
1:(N1)
] for the IPV model when the support of c is bounded from below
by c > −∞.
Proof. The equilibrium bid function is given by
β(c; N) = c +
R
c
[1 F (ξ)]
N1
[1 F (c)]
N1
Then the minimum bid is
β(c; N) = c +
R
c
[1 F (ξ)]
N1
[1 F (c)]
N1
= c +
Z
c
[1 F (ξ)]
N1
= c + ξ[1 F (ξ)]
N1
|
c
+
Z
c
ξ(N 1)f(ξ)[1 F (ξ)]
N2
= c + (0 c) +
Z
c
ξ(N 1)f(ξ)[1 F (ξ)]
N2
= E[c
1:(N1)
]
Where the third line comes from integration by parts. Here we require the assumption that
lim
ξ→∞
f(ξ)[1 F (ξ)]
N
= 0, so that
ξ[1 F (ξ)]
N1
|
c
= lim
γ0
[1 F (
1
γ
)]
N1
γ
c[1 F (c)]
N1
= lim
γ0
(N 1)f(
1
γ
)[1 F (
1
γ
)]
N2
1
c
= 0 c
Lemma 3. The expected k-th order statistic of N draws can be written in terms of the expected
k-th and (k + 1) th order statistics from N + 1 draws: E[c
k:N
] =
k
N+1
E[c
(k+1):(N +1)
] +
N+1k
N+1
E[c
k:(N +1)
]
69
Proof. First, examining the difference between the k-th order statistics of N and N + 1 draws.
Expressing E[c
k:N
] E[c
k:(N +1)
] and rearranging terms gives:
E[c
k:N
] E[c
k:(N +1)
]
=
Z
N!
(k 1)!(N k)!
cf(c)F (c)
k1
[1 F (c)]
N k
dc
Z
(N + 1)!
(k 1)!(N + 1 k)!
cf(c)F (c)
k1
[1 F (c)]
N +1k
dc
=
Z
N!(N + 1 k)
(k 1)!(N + 1 k)!
(N + 1)!
(k 1)!(N + 1 k)!
[1 F (c)]
cf(c)F (c)
k1
[1 F (c)]
N k
dc
=
Z
(N + 1)!
(k 1)!(N + 1 k)!
cf(c)F (c)
k
[1 F (c)]
N k
dc
Z
kN!
(k 1)!(N + 1 k)!
cf(c)F (c)
k1
[1 F (c)]
N k
dc
=
k
(N + 1 k)
E[c
(k+1):(N +1)
] E[c
k:N
]
Rearranging, we obtain
E[c
k:N
] =
k
N+1
E[c
(k+1):(N +1)
] +
N+1k
N+1
E[c
k:(N +1)
].
E.2 Proof of Proposition 5
Consider the entry equation
E[π
n
· U · h(x)|n, T ] k(m)· > 0 N n (20)
= E[π
n
|n, T ] ·
h(x)
k(m)
> ε N n (21)
For any realization (T, x, m), there exists (T, x
0
, m
0
) such that Pr(N n|T, x, m) = Pr(N
n|T, x
0
, m
0
) for all N.
43
Using these values x
0
and m
0
that provide the same conditional distri-
bution of N, calculate:
E[B · U · h(x)|N, T, x, m]
E[B · U · h(x
0
)|N, t, x
0
, m
0
]
=
E[B|N, t] · E[U|N, T, x, m] · h(x)
E[B|N, t] · E[U|N, t, x
0
, m
0
] · h(x
0
)
=
h(x)
h(x
0
)
. (22)
As h(x) is normalized to 1 at x = x
0
, h(·) is identified.
Once h(·) is identified, E[B|N, T, x, m] is identified by calculating the mean of the scaled
(conditional) winning bid E[
1
h(x)
B · U · h(x)|N, T, x, m]. Recall that B · U · h(x) is the observed
winning bid.
k(·) is identified by the relation
h(x)
k(m)
=
h(x
0
)
k(m
0
)
(23)
based on the identification of h(·) and the normalization k(m
0
) = 1 for an arbitrary m
0
.
Relative profits are identified by considering different values of x and m that generate N
and N
0
6= N with the same probability. For every (N, T, x, m), there exists (N
0
, T, x
0
, m
0
) for
43
Here, and once more in the proof, I rely on either h(·) or k(·) having broad support.
70
which Pr(N n|T, x, m) = Pr(N
0
n|T, x
0
, m
0
). Here, I re-use notation; x
0
and m
0
are
different from the first part of this section. Thus, the entry condition
E[π
N
|N, T ] ·
h(x)
k(m)
= E[π
N
0
|N
0
, t] ·
h(x
0
)
k(m
0
)
(24)
can be used to solve for
E[π
N
|N,T ]
E[π
N
0
|N
0
,T ]
, as h(·) and k(·) are identified. Analogously, relative profits
E[π
N
|N,T ]
E[π
N
|N,T
0
]
are identified.
It is straightforward to extend these identification results to setting in which sellers observe
U prior to entry. This is possible because the distribution of U conditional on (T, x, m) will be
equal to the distribution of U conditional on (T, x
0
, m
0
).
E.3 Proof of Proposition 6
The ratio of expected profits for n and n
0
conditional on T is given by
R =
E[π
n
|n, T ]
E[π
n
0
|n
0
, T ]
=
1
n
(E[B|n, T ] E[C|n, T ])
1
n
0
(E[B|n
0
, T ] E[C|n
0
, T ])
(25)
As shown by Proposition 5, R is identified. Let n
0
= n + 1.
When the selection mechanism is a symmetric auction. E[B|n, T ] = E[C
2:n
|T ] and E[C|n, T ] =
E[C
1:n
|T ]. From here on I suppress notation indicating that costs are conditional on T . From
Lemma (3), we have E[C
1:n
] =
1
n+1
E[C
2:(n+1)
]+
n
n+1
E[C
1:(n+1)
]. Plugging this into the equation
for R obtains
R
E[C
2:(n+1)
] E[C
1:(n+1)
]
= E[C
2:n
]
1
n + 1
E[C
2:(n+1)
]
n
n + 1
E[C
1:(n+1)
]
R +
n
n + 1
E[C
1:(n+1)
] = E[C
2:n
]
R +
1
n + 1
E[C
2:(n+1)
]
E[C
2:(n+1)
] and E[C
2:(n+1)
] are equivalent to E[B|N = n] and E[B|N = n + 1], both of
which are identified by Proposition 5. Therefore, E[C
1:(n+1)
] is identified. E[C
1:n
] is obtained
from equation (25). These are sufficient to identify seller surplus.
Once seller surplus is identified, the distribution of ε is identified from equation (21) by
using variation in h(·) or k(·).
E.4 Proof of Proposition 7
For each observed sequential value of N {N, ..., N}, the first-order and second-order statistics
of N draws from the cost distribution are identified (see Propositions 5 and 6). Using the
recursive relationship of order statistics shown in Lemma 3, these are equivalent to identifying
the first N N + 2 expected order statistics from N draws of C.
71
E.5 Alternative Identification and a Note on Independent Private Values
The model in this paper allows for endogenous entry. To separate the private cost distribution
from unobservable heterogeneity, I make use of a entry cost shifter m to generate exogenous
variation in N. Without endogenous entry, there is no entry cost shifter and the entry equation
cannot be used to identify the model. When N is purely exogenous, variation in N can still be
used to separately identify the private and common cost distributions.
Proposition 10. First-price, symmetric auctions with unobserved heterogeneity and conditionally
independent private values are identified when only the winning bid and the number of bidders
is observed. In particular, seller surplus and the first (N N + 2) expected order statistics of N
draws from F are identified. Identification is obtained without modeling entry as long as there is
no selection on unobservables.
The result can be generalized to auction settings that are independent of the duration-
setting problem. Thus, this identification result may prove practical. With only the winning
bid and variation in the number of bidders, researchers can estimate a model with unobserved
heterogeneity, which is far less restrictive than the assumption of independent private values
(IPV) that is common in such settings with limited data.
This implies that in any setting where estimation is motivated by IPV, one could also es-
timate a conditional independent private values model with unobserved heterogeneity. The
econometrician may expect that unobserved heterogeneity is present, and this provides a theo-
retical background to test for its importance. In Appendix G, I detail a computational approach
that greatly speeds up the maximum likelihood estimation of these models.
Proof. The ratio of second-order statistics is identified by comparing winning bids B · U · h(x)
for different values of n and n
0
.
E[B|n, T, x, m] · E[U |n, T, x, m] · h(x)
E[B|n
0
, T, x, m] · E[U|n
0
, T, x, m] · h(x)
=
E[C
2:n
|T, x, m]
E[C
2:n
0
|T, x, m]
(26)
where E[U|n, T, x, m] = E[U|n
0
, T, x, m] = E[U|T, x, m] by independence and no selection on
unobservables.
From here on, C
i
and U may be conditional on (T, x, m). I suppress this in my notation for
clarity. Normalizing E[U ] = 1 pins down the scale of E[C
2:n
].
44
Suppose that another (
ˆ
F ,
ˆ
G) rationalizes the data. Then
B
n
· U
d
=
ˆ
B
n
·
ˆ
U
B
n
0
· U
d
=
ˆ
B
n
0
·
ˆ
U
44
Note that, in practice, we may normalize E[U|T, x, m] = 1 for all (T, x, m) realizations. How the mean of
C
2:n
· U changes is captures in changes to the mean of C.
72
Construct
˜
b
n
0
,
˜
ˆ
b
n
0
,
˜
U, and
˜
ˆ
U as random variables that are independent of and have the same
conditional distributions as their tilde-free counterparts. Then it follows that
(B
n
· U) ·
˜
ˆ
B
n
0
·
˜
ˆ
U
d
=
ˆ
B
n
·
ˆ
U
·
˜
B
n
0
·
˜
U
= B
n
·
˜
ˆ
B
n
0
d
=
ˆ
B
n
·
˜
B
n
0
From this relation, we may take the minimum on both sides. By independence and Lemma
2, I obtain
E[C
1:(n1)
] · E[
ˆ
C
1:(n
0
1)
] = E[
ˆ
C
1:(n1)
] · E[C
1:(n
0
1)
]
E[C
1:(n1)
]
E[C
1:(n
0
1)
]
=
E[
ˆ
C
1:(n1)
]
E[
ˆ
C
1:(n
0
1)
]
That is, any (
ˆ
F ,
ˆ
G) that rationalizes the data has a private cost distribution with the same
ratio of first order statistics.
Finally, using the fact that E[C
1:(n1)
] =
1
n
E[C
2:n
] +
n1
n
E[C
1:n
], we can link together these
ratios when n
0
= n + 1.
1
n
E[C
2:n
] +
n1
n
E[C
1:n
]
E[C
1:n
]
=
1
n
E[
ˆ
C
2:n
] +
n1
n
E[
ˆ
C
1:n
]
E[
ˆ
C
1:n
]
=
E[C
2:n
]
E[C
1:n
]
=
E[
ˆ
C
2:n
]
E[
ˆ
C
1:n
]
As we have identified E[C
2:n
], E[C
1:n
] and E[C
1:(n1)
] is also identified. Therefore,
ˆ
F and
F have the same ratio of second-order statistics. With sequential values of N {N , ..., N }, we
can iterate forward from the from the identified first-order and second-order statistics using the
recursive relationship between order statistics from Lemma 3. Therefore,
ˆ
F and F and identical
up to the first N N + 2 expected order statistics from N draws of C.
73
F A Model with Microfoundations
In the empirical application of this paper, I employ a “reduced-form” approach to a capturing
how the distribution of private costs changes with T. Here, I provide a model of underlying costs
that generates both the distribution of costs and how duration affects the distribution. Suppose
that instantaneous costs follow an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck diffusion process. The continuous-time
cost process X
t
is governed by the differential equation
dx
t
= θ(µ x
t
) + γdW
t
where W
t
is a Wiener process. This process is stationary over t. That is, any contract with
duration T will have the same unconditional distribution as any other contract with duration
T . Define the average cost over time T as
c
T
=
1
T
Z
X
t
dt
Then c
T
is Gaussian with mean µ and variance σ
2
=
1
T
2
γ
2
θ
3
θT + e
θT
1
. When costs are
Gaussian, E[c
1:N
(σ)] = E[z
1:N
]σ + µ, where z is a standard normal.
First, consider the efficient contract. Let ξ(T ) = σ =
q
1
T
2
γ
2
θ
3
(θT + e
θT
1). For ease of
exposition, assume β = 1. The efficient contract T solves
min
T
E[z
1:N
]ξ(T ) + µ +
δ
T
.
As E[z
1:N
] is negative and the variance of c
T
is decreasing with T , the average expected
supply cost µ + E[z
1:N
]ξ(T ) is increasing with T . In this microfounded model, the increasing
supply costs over many periods is due the idiosyncratic variation over time. The mean expected
supply cost for each bidder, µ, is constant over time.
Likewise, the same analysis applies to the buyer-optimal contract when N > 3. The buyer
solves the same problem where the second-order statistic E[z
2:N
] is substituted for E[z
1:N
]. For
N {2, 3}, E[z
2:N
] > 0.
F.1 Relating Competition to Contract Duration
The first-order condition from the problem above is
E[z
1:N
]ξ
0
(T ) =
δ
T
2
ξ
0
(T )T
2
=
δ
E[z
1:N
]
. (27)
In this case, we obtain a monotonic relationship between the number of bidders and the
74
optimal duration, as N has a monotonic effect on the right-hand side. Unlike the U-shape
models, the microfounded model here does not have a lower bound on costs.
Proposition 11. The efficient duration is decreasing in the number of bidders.
Proof.
d
dT
ξ
0
(T )T
2
= 2T · ξ
0
(T ) T
2
ξ
00
(T ). Combining the second-order conditions and
first-order conditions, we obtain.
E[z
1:N
]ξ
00
(T ) >
2
T
E[z
1:N
]ξ
0
(T )
= T
2
· ξ
00
(T ) < 2Tξ
0
(T )
An increase in N increases the RHS of equation 27. As
d
dT
ξ
0
(T )T
2
< 0, the optimal T
falls.
We now turn to the buyer-optimal contract, which solves the same problem where the
second-order statistic E[z
2:N
] is substituted for E[z
1:N
].
Proposition 12. The buyer-optimal duration is decreasing in the number of bidders. It is optimal
for the buyer to issue a permanent contract for N {2, 3}.
The permanent contract result follows from the fact that the second-order statistic is greater
than zero with a small N.
Additionally, we have that E[z
1:N
] < E[z
2:N
]. Therefore,
Proposition 13. The efficient duration is less than the buyer-optimal duration.
75
G Likelihood Function
For estimation, we obtain the likelihoods for Y
n
and N given by
f
Y
n
|N,X,T,M
=
Z
f
B
n
|T,N
(
y
U
1
h(x)
)
1
U
1
h(x)
f
U|N,T,x,m
(U)dU
Pr(N = n|T, x, m) =
Z
Pr(N = n|U, T, x, m)f
U|T,x,m
(U)dU
For estimation, I make the assumption that U (X, M). As U is not observed by the buyer
when setting T , U (T, x, m). This simplifies the problem so that f
U|T,x,m
(U) = f
U
(U).
The conditional distribution of U used in the likelihood of Y
N
is given by f
U|N,T,x,m
(u) =
Pr(N=n|U,T,x,m)f
U
(u)
Pr(N=n|T,x,m)
. This simplifies so that the joint contribution is given by
f
Y
n
|N,X,T,M
(y
n
) · Pr(N = n|T, x, m) =
Z
f
B
n
|T,N
(
y
u
1
h(x)
)
1
u
1
h(x)
f
U|N,T,x,m
(u)du
Pr(N = n|T, x, m)
=
Z
f
B
n
|T,N
(
y
u
1
h(x)
)
1
u
1
h(x)
Pr(N = n|u, T, x, m)f
U
(u)
Pr(N = n|T, x, m)
du
Pr(N = n|T, x, m)
=
Z
f
B
n
|T,N
(
y
u
1
h(x)
)
1
u
1
h(x)
Pr(N = n|u, T, x, m)f
U
(u)du
With the assumption that the shock ε is independent of (U, T, x, m), we have the following
expression for conditional probability of N.
Pr(N = n|U, T, x, m) = F
ln ε
(ln E[π
n
|T ] + ln h(x) + ln U ln k(m))
F
ln ε
(ln E[π
n+1
|T ] + ln h(x) + ln U ln k(m))
I use the joint likelihood of Y
n
and N to obtain estimates for cost and entry parameters.
G.1 A Computational Innovation
In this setting, there is a symmetric equilibrium in which each bidder has a monotone bid
function β(·; n) mapping private costs to the submitted bid. The density of an observed bid is
given by
f
b
(b; n) = f
c
(β
1
(b; n))
1
β
0
(β
1
(b; n))
In maximum likelihood estimation of the cost distribution, it is necessary to invert the bid
function to calculate the density. This can be computationally intensive when β does not have
a closed-form solution.
In the presence of unobserved heterogeneity, the density of the observed bid
˜
B = B · U is
76
given by the convolution when B U.
f
˜
b
(
˜
b) =
Z
u
u
f
b
˜
b
u
!
1
u
f
u
(u)du
=
Z
u
u
f
c
β
1
˜
b
u
; n
!!
1
β
0
β
1
˜
b
u
; n

1
u
f
u
(u)du
Here, the computational burden increases greatly. Integrating out the unobserved hetero-
geneity means that the bid function must be inverted for each value of u within the integral in
order to calculate β
1
˜
b
u
; n
. As the inverse bid function has an analytic solution for only a
few specialized cases, in practice this computation relies on a non-linear equation solver or an
approximation. Thus, the calculations are constrained by the efficiency and accuracy of such
an approach.
One easy-to-implement solution that makes maximum likelihood significantly more tractable
is to use a change-of-variables to calculate the density. Instead of integrating out the unobserved
heterogeneity by integrating over u, replace u with u =
˜
b
β(c)
and integrate over c. The density
then becomes:
f
˜
b
(
˜
b) =
Z
u
u
f
c
β
1
˜
b
u
!!
1
β
0
β
1
˜
b
u

1
u
f
u
(u)du
=
Z
ψ
1
(u)
ψ
1
(u)
f
c
β
1
(β(c))
1
β
0
(β
1
(β(c)))
β(c)
˜
b
f
u
˜
b
β(c)
!
˜
b
β(c)
2
β
0
(c)
!
dc
=
Z
c
c
f
c
(c) f
u
˜
b
β(c)
!
1
β(c)
dc
Note that in this form, there is no need to invert the bid function. As the general form for
the symmetric equilibrium bid function is
β(c) = c +
R
c
[1 F (z)]
n1
[1 F (c)]
n1
,
the primary computational cost is a numerical integration routine. Therefore, the model is
computationally tractable for a vast class of parametric distributions of C and U , as well as
nonparametric approximations such as B-splines. This innovation can also apply to models
with additively separable unobserved heterogeneity as well. When
˜
B = B + U, then
f
˜
b
(
˜
b) =
Z
u
u
f
c
β
1
˜
b u

f
u
(u)du =
Z
c
c
f
c
(c) f
u
˜
b β(c)
β
0
(c)
dc.
77
H Supplemental Empirical Results
H.1 Distributions of Bidder Costs
Figure 10: Distribution of Bidder Costs
(a) Duration-Dependent Private Costs
0.00
0.03
0.06
0.09
0 10 20 30 40
Private Costs (Annual)
Density
Duration
1
5
(b) Unobservable Auction-Specific Heterogeneity
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
0 1 2 3
Multiplicative Unobserved Auction−Specific Costs
Density
Notes: The figure plots the distributions of the unobservable components of bidder costs.
Private costs are displayed in panel (a), and the density of unobserved auction-specific
heterogeneity is displayed in panel (b). In panel (a), the density is plotted for a one-
year contract and a five-year contract. The estimated parameters indicate an increasing
mean and a decreasing variance in private costs with contract duration. The density shifts
smoothly between these functions for intermediate values of duration.
78
H.2 Projecting Transaction Costs on Location Type and Agency
Table 17: Dependent Variable: ln(Transaction Costs)
(1) (2)
Location Type: Accommodations 1.436
∗∗∗
(0.278) 0.249 (0.219)
Location Type: Airport 0.414 (0.264) 0.543
∗∗∗
(0.203)
Location Type: Field Office 0.027 (0.125) 0.068 (0.095)
Location Type: Industrial 1.150
∗∗∗
(0.325) 0.331 (0.254)
Location Type: Medical 1.530
∗∗∗
(0.256) 0.294 (0.201)
Location Type: Office 0.000 (.) 0.000 (.)
Location Type: Research 0.371
∗∗
(0.157) 0.232
(0.120)
Location Type: Services 0.180 (0.207) 0.005 (0.158)
Location Type: Technical 1.403
∗∗∗
(0.272) 0.285 (0.212)
Location Type: Visitors 0.784
∗∗∗
(0.196) 0.319
∗∗
(0.152)
Department: Agriculture 0.309
∗∗
(0.123) 0.183
(0.096)
Department: Commerce 0.559
∗∗∗
(0.177) 0.292
∗∗
(0.137)
Department: Defense 0.000 (.) 0.000 (.)
Department: GSA 1.577
∗∗∗
(0.240) 0.418
∗∗
(0.189)
Department: Homeland Security 1.645
∗∗∗
(0.217) 0.650
∗∗∗
(0.171)
Department: Interior 0.440
∗∗
(0.193) 0.095 (0.149)
Department: Other 1.071
∗∗∗
(0.252) 0.256 (0.195)
Department: Veterans Affairs 0.177 (0.235) 0.404
∗∗
(0.180)
ln(Square Footage) 0.601
∗∗∗
(0.026)
ln(Weekly Frequency) 0.431
∗∗∗
(0.059)
Standard errors in parentheses
p < 0.10,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗∗
p < 0.01
Notes: The table displays results for regressions of estimated (log) transaction costs on location
type and department, with additional controls in specification (2). N =1,046.
79
H.3 Incumbency and Asymmetries
In this section, I present regressions for the dependent variables of price and the number of
bids, including an indicator for whether or not a single incumbent bidder was identified from
a previous contract. That is, the indicator equals one if building cleaning services for the same
agency and 9-digit ZIP code were performed by a single supplier in the previous year. The
coefficient on this variable is not significant, and its inclusion does not meaningfully impact the
estimated coefficients.
Table 18: Descriptive Regressions: Incumbency Check, Price
IV-1 (a) IV-1 (b) IV-1 (c) IV-2 (a) IV-2 (b) IV-2 (c)
Number of Bids 0.053
∗∗
0.052
∗∗
0.052
∗∗
0.047
∗∗
0.046
∗∗
0.046
∗∗
(0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022)
Duration (Years) 0.043
∗∗∗
0.043
∗∗∗
0.043
∗∗∗
0.033
∗∗
0.033
∗∗
0.033
∗∗
(0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.015) (0.015) (0.015)
ln(Square Footage) 0.689
∗∗∗
0.688
∗∗∗
0.688
∗∗∗
0.687
∗∗∗
0.686
∗∗∗
0.686
∗∗∗
(0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024)
ln(Weekly Frequency) 0.467
∗∗∗
0.467
∗∗∗
0.467
∗∗∗
0.407
∗∗∗
0.407
∗∗∗
0.407
∗∗∗
(0.041) (0.041) (0.041) (0.040) (0.040) (0.040)
ln(2004 Unemp.) 0.080
∗∗∗
0.080
∗∗∗
0.080
∗∗∗
0.060
∗∗∗
0.060
∗∗∗
0.060
∗∗∗
(0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018)
High-Intensity Cleaning 0.559
∗∗∗
0.559
∗∗∗
0.559
∗∗∗
0.076 0.076 0.077
(0.075) (0.075) (0.075) (0.125) (0.125) (0.125)
Follow-On Contract 0.018 0.003
(0.053) (0.050)
Incumbent Winner 0.012 0.008
(0.106) (0.100)
Site Type FEs X X X
Observations 1046 1046 1046 1046 1046 1046
R
2
0.69 0.69 0.69 0.73 0.73 0.73
Standard errors in parentheses
p < 0.10,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗∗
p < 0.01
Notes: The table displays regression results for regressions of log annual price on auction characteristics and
local market characteristics. Specifications IV-1 (a) and IV-2 (a) are two-stage least squares regressions and
are identical to the descriptive regressions in Table 2. The (b) specifications include an additional regressor
indicating whether the contract is a follow-on contract and the (c) specifications include an indicator for
whether the contract was won by an incumbent bidder in a follow-on contract.
80
Table 19: Descriptive Regressions: Incumbency Check, Number of Bids
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Duration (Years) 0.002 0.005 0.009 0.002 0.005 0.009
(0.099) (0.099) (0.099) (0.100) (0.100) (0.100)
ln(Square Footage) 0.834
∗∗∗
0.835
∗∗∗
0.840
∗∗∗
0.825
∗∗∗
0.824
∗∗∗
0.829
∗∗∗
(0.106) (0.106) (0.106) (0.112) (0.112) (0.112)
ln(Weekly Frequency) 0.009 0.014 0.010 0.137 0.146 0.141
(0.253) (0.253) (0.253) (0.257) (0.258) (0.257)
ln(2004 Unemp.) 0.794
∗∗∗
0.809
∗∗∗
0.813
∗∗∗
0.793
∗∗∗
0.808
∗∗∗
0.811
∗∗∗
(0.238) (0.239) (0.239) (0.238) (0.238) (0.238)
ln(Unemployment) 1.420
∗∗∗
1.432
∗∗∗
1.436
∗∗∗
1.356
∗∗∗
1.366
∗∗∗
1.370
∗∗∗
(0.231) (0.231) (0.231) (0.231) (0.231) (0.231)
ln(Num. Firms in Zip3) 0.257
0.248
0.250
0.276
0.267
0.269
(0.148) (0.148) (0.148) (0.147) (0.147) (0.147)
Generic Set-Aside 1.134
∗∗∗
1.125
∗∗∗
1.131
∗∗∗
0.987
∗∗∗
0.982
∗∗∗
0.985
∗∗∗
(0.350) (0.350) (0.350) (0.361) (0.361) (0.361)
High-Intensity Cleaning 0.294 0.303 0.305
(0.475) (0.475) (0.475)
Follow-On Contract 0.351 0.353
(0.326) (0.326)
Incumbent Winner 0.836 0.814
(0.650) (0.646)
Site Type FEs X X X
Observations 1046 1046 1046 1046 1046 1046
R
2
0.17 0.17 0.17 0.19 0.19 0.19
Standard errors in parentheses
p < 0.10,
∗∗
p < 0.05,
∗∗∗
p < 0.01
Notes: The table displays regression results for regressions of number of bids on auction characteristics and
local labor market variables. Specifications (1) and (4) are equivalent to the descriptive regressions (3) and
(4) in Table 3. The additional specifications included indicators for whether the contract is a follow-on contract
or whether the contract was won by an incumbent bidder in a follow-on contract.
81
H.4 Detailed Impacts of Standardized Duration
Table 20: Percent Impact of Uniform Term Policies
¯
T Affected Price Trans. Cost Total Cost Count
1 All 11.2 317.1 33.7 1046
T >
¯
T 11.8 334.2 35.5 995
T <
¯
T 1.5 36.6 0.6 23
2 All 7.5 108.5 9.0 1046
T >
¯
T 8.7 125.4 10.0 930
T <
¯
T 4.1 50.5 2.3 62
3 All 3.9 39.0 2.9 1046
T >
¯
T 6.3 61.8 3.4 761
T <
¯
T 5.1 42.6 2.7 146
4 All 0.4 4.3 1.3 1046
T >
¯
T 3.2 24.0 0.7 686
T <
¯
T 6.0 39.1 2.9 306
5 All 3.1 16.6 1.5 1046
T >
¯
T 2.0 12.2 0.3 18
T <
¯
T 6.9 36.8 3.3 478
Notes: The table displays the average percent changes (by contract, not in aggre-
gate) in total costs, prices, and annualized transaction costs when all contracts
are issued in standardized durations corresponding to
¯
T . For a uniform duration
policy of 4 years or less, the average price paid decreases and the amount spent
on transaction costs increases. The final column lists the count of the affected
contracts. The first column indicates the group affected by the policy. Rows cor-
responding to T >
¯
T pertain to all contracts that see a reduction in duration, and
the reported effects are equivalent to a policy that caps duration at
¯
T .
82