Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
International Finance Discussion Papers
Number 1101
March 2014
Evaluating Asset-Market Effects of Unconventional
Monetary Policy: A Cross-Country Comparison
John H. Rogers
Federal Reserve Board
Chiara Scotti
Federal Reserve Board
Jonathan H. Wright
Johns Hopkins
NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate
discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers
(other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared
with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/.
This paper can be downloaded without charge from Social Science Research Network electronic library at
http://www.ssrn.com/.
Evaluating Asset-Market Effects of Unconventional
Monetary Policy: A Cross-Country Comparison
John H. Rogers
Chiara Scotti
Jonathan H. Wright
§
March 7, 2014
Abstract
This paper examines the effects of unconventional monetary policy by the Fed-
eral Reserve, Bank of England, European Central Bank and Bank of Japan
on bond yields, stock prices and exchange rates. We use common methodolo-
gies for the four central banks, with daily and intradaily asset price data. We
emphasize the use of intradaily data to identify the causal effect of monetary
policy surprises. We find that these policies are effective in easing financial con-
ditions when policy rates are stuck at the zero lower bound, apparently largely
by reducing term premia.
We are grateful to David Bowman, Chris Erceg, Joseph Gagnon, Philip Lane, David opez-
Salido, Edward Nelson, Charlie Thomas, Beth-Anne Wilson, Egon Zakrajsek and two anonymous
referees for helpful comments. We thank Rebecca DeSimone and Eric English for outstanding
research assistance. All errors are ours alone. The views expressed in this paper are solely the
responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve
System.
International Finance Division, Federal Reserve Board, Washington DC 20551;
International Finance Division, Federal Reserve Board, Washington DC 20551;
§
Department of Economics, Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore MD 21218; wrightj@jhu.edu.
JEL Classification: C22, E43, E48
Keywords: Large scale asset purchases, quantitative easing, zero bound, term premium.
1 Introduction
Over recent years, short-term nominal interest rates in many countries have effectively
been driven to the zero lower bound.
1
Deprived of their traditional tool for policy,
the four major central banks have begun adopting unconventional monetary policy,
including forward rate guidance, asset purchases and programs to directly support
bank lending. These unconventional policies differ across central banks, but have
many points in common (Lenza et al., 2010).
Unfortunately, measuring the effects of monetary policy on other asset prices in
this environment poses special challenges. In normal times, the lumpy manner in
which monetary policy news is released to the public is a powerful source of iden-
tification. One can define a monetary policy surprise as the difference between the
central bank’s announcement concerning the short-term interest rate and the ex-ante
expectation of this announcement, measured from interest rate futures quotes (Kut-
tner, 2001). And then one can study how other asset prices respond to monetary
policy news, probably safe in the assumption that in a short window around the an-
nouncement, this news is the only driver of asset prices. But with unconventional
policy, there is no clear measure of the central bank’s policy stance, and no easy way
to determine policy expectations. Thus, the simple event-study methodology breaks
down.
But even in the era of unconventional policy, news still comes out in a lumpy
manner. The news is just harder to measure. A number of approaches have been
used to attempt to adapt the conventional event-study approach to examine the effects
of monetary policy surprises in this new environment. Some authors, such as Doh
1
When we talk about the zero lower bound, we don’t mean that short-term interest rates are
necessarily driven precisely to zero. For institutional and technical reasons, most central banks have
kept short rates a little above zero. Still, for all practical purposes, the US, UK, euro area and
Japan are all effectively at the zero lower bound.
1
(2010), Gagnon et al. (2011), Meaning and Zhu (2011), Neely (2010), Krishnamurthy
and Vissing-Jorgenson (2011), Joyce and Tong (2012) and Swanson (2011), have
identified announcements that they argue are complete surprises, and then simply
added up the jumps in asset prices in short windows bracketing these announcements.
2
This strategy hinges on the entire announcement being unexpected, as was arguably
the case for some important announcements by the Federal Reserve (Fed) and the
Bank of England (BOE) in 2008 and 2009. But most monetary policy announcements
have been at least in part anticipated, with news coming out in a gradual manner
before the announcement.
Another approach, considered by Cahill et al. (2013) and Joyce et al. (2011), is
to estimate the effects of the surprise component of asset purchase announcements,
using survey expectations to measure these surprises. However, surveys have limited
data availability (both in terms of sample period and questions asked) and are not
necessarily perfect measures of investors’ beliefs.
3
We take a different approach in this paper, which is however limited to measuring
the relative effects of monetary policy on different asset prices. We define the mon-
etary policy surprise as the intraday change in government bond yields right around
the announcement, and then regress other asset returns around the announcement
on this measure of the monetary policy surprise. There are two important caveats
to this methodology. First, it only measures the pass-through from a given change
in government bond yields (caused by monetary policy) onto other asset prices, not
the efficacy of monetary policy in affecting government bond yields. But this is still
2
Some researchers examine the effects of central bank purchases of specific securities as opposed to
announcements, for example Ghysels et al. (2012) for the ECB Securities Market Program, D’Amico
and King (2013) for the US, or Meaning and Zhu (2011) for the US and UK. We are however focusing
on monetary policy announcements.
3
For example, the announcement at the June 2013 FOMC meeting about the timeline for ending
asset purchases was not far from survey expectations and yet roiled global fixed income markets.
2
an important question, as several researchers have questioned the ability of declines
in sovereign bond yields to be transmitted into other asset prices (Eggertsson and
Woodford, 2003; Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgenson, 2013). Second, it measures
the composite effects of monetary policy on asset prices, without decomposing it into
the effects of specific policies, such as forward guidance or asset purchases. It is dif-
ficult to separate the effects of these different types of unconventional policy, since
many announcements covered policies of multiple types. But we do also make an
attempt to separate out the effects of different types of unconventional monetary pol-
icy announcements. We also attempt to estimate the persistence of announcement
effects—an important, but particularly difficult task.
Especially in the current environment, the event study methodology is of far
more than academic interest. Policymakers have seen the immediate effects of news
announcements on asset prices, and we strongly suspect that this has in turn helped
to persuade them of the benefits of some unconventional monetary policies. This is
perhaps particularly true for the European Central Bank (ECB).
In this paper, we focus on using intradaily data where possible. The use of in-
tradaily data is potentially helpful to zero in on the window where monetary policy
is the only information coming out (Faust et al., 2007; G¨urkaynak and Wright, 2013).
However, in the current environment, announcements are complicated, and take time
to digest, and are often explained in subsequent press conferences. Consequently,
the assumption that the monetary policy surprise can be directly measured from the
jumps in government bond yields in an intradaily window around the announcement
time may be questionable. Too narrow a window will miss part of the monetary
policy news, but yet too wide a window will contaminate the monetary policy news
with other shocks. Mindful of this concern, we also consider another closely-related
approach, which is identification through heteroskedasticity, employing the method-
3
ology of Rigobon and Sack (2003a,b, 2004, 2005). This only requires us to assume
that days of monetary policy announcements are days on which the variance of mone-
tary policy shocks was especially high—a much weaker restriction. Papers employing
these methods include Gilchrist and Zakrajsek (2013), Raskin (2013), Arai (2013)
and Wright (2012).
The literature on using event-study and related methodologies to measure the
asset price effects of monetary policy shocks in the era of unconventional monetary
policy is large and growing fast. Our paper uses the same general methodologies that
are used in existing work. However, our paper has some novel aspects, such as the
emphasis on intradaily data. And it conducts the analysis on a consistent basis for
the four main advanced-economy central banks: the Fed, the ECB, the BOE and the
Bank of Japan (BOJ).
The plan for the remainder of this paper is as follows. Section 2 summarizes
country experiences with unconventional monetary policy, updating the narrative of
Lenza et al. (2010). Section 3 proposes intraday measures of monetary policy surprises
and examines their effects on other asset prices. Section 4 embeds this identification
of monetary policy shocks in a structural VAR, to estimate the persistence of effects.
Section 5 considers the strategy of identification through heteroskedasticity. Section
6 contains some discussion of policy implications. Section 7 concludes.
2 Country Experiences with Unconventional Policy
2.1 United States
In the United States, by late 2008 the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) had
brought the federal funds rate close to zero—effectively, its lower bound. With the
4
traditional tool for expansionary monetary policy thus sidelined, the FOMC turned to
unconventional policy options: “forward guidance” about future policy and large-scale
asset purchases (LSAPs). Forward guidance began with simple and general remarks
in the FOMC statements: “economic conditions are likely to warrant exceptionally
low levels of the federal funds rate for an extended period.” This was enhanced in
August 2011, when the Committee specified “at least through mid-2013” in place of
“an extended period.” The projected end date was pushed into the future several
times, and in September 2012 it was shifted to mid-2015. Forward guidance was
further enhanced with efforts to provide clarity about the economic conditions that
would lead to an unwinding of the unconventional stimulus policies. In January 2012,
the FOMC released a statement specifying its longer-run goals on inflation (2 percent)
and the “normal” rate of unemployment (5.2-6 percent). Meanwhile, the Committee
clarified how it would use the federal funds rate to achieve these dual objectives. In
December 2012, the Committee replaced its “calendar guidance” with a statement
anticipating that exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate will be appropriate
“at least as long as the unemployment rate remains above 6 1/2 percent, inflation
between one and two years ahead is projected to be no more than a half percentage
point above the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run goal, and longer-term inflation
expectations continue to be well anchored.”
The FOMC has also authorized a series of large scale asset purchases (LSAPs)
of longer term securities. Starting in late 2008, the Fed has purchased longer-term
government agency debt securities and mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and longer-
term Treasury securities. These purchase, which were intended to lower longer-term
interest rates and raise asset prices, added over $2.5 trillion to Federal Reserve as-
sets. The first LSAP program, involving agency debt and MBS, was announced in
November 2008. The purchase program was later stepped up and broadened to in-
5
clude longer term Treasury securities. The first round of LSAPs was completed in
March 2010. In November 2010, purchases were again stepped up with reinvestment
arrangements, under which the Fed redeployed the principal payments from agency
securities into purchases of longer term Treasuries. From then until June 2011, the
Fed’s second LSAP program (QE2) involved the purchase of $600 billion in longer
term Treasuries. Since then the FOMC has continued to maintain the level of secu-
rities holdings attained under the LSAPs, with further adjustments to its investment
policy including a shift towards a longer average maturity for its Treasury portfolio.
The two tenets of U.S. monetary policy, forward guidance and LSAPs, are naturally
intertwined, thus posing challenges to econometric identification. The effects of asset
purchases depend on expectations of (1) the total value of intended purchases and
(2) how long the FOMC intends to hold them. If the Committee buys today but
sells tomorrow, there will be little effect on those asset prices. To make LSAPs as
effective as possible, the FOMC has attempted to communicate the intended path of
holdings years into the future. These communications issues have become the subject
of considerable discussion in recent months.
2.2 United Kingdom
As part of its response to the global financial crisis and domestic economic downturn,
the BOE Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) cut its policy rate from 5 percent in
October 2008 to 0.5 percent, its effective lower bound, in March 2009. But the
Committee also decided it needed to ease monetary conditions further in March 2009
through a £75 billion Asset Purchase program (APF) to purchase public sector assets
6
with residual maturity of 5-25 years financed by creation of central bank money.
4
The
APF size was gradually increased from £75 billion to £200 billion in February of 2010.
Following a pause, the MPC resumed increasing the size of the APF in October 2011,
reaching £375 billion by the end of 2012. In addition to the £375 billion financed
by reserve issuance, the BOE is also authorized to purchase up to £10 billion in
private assets financed by Treasury issuance
5
. But at the time of writing, the APF
has no such assets. The BOE is indemnified by the UK Treasury against losses on
the APF. On August 7 2013, BOE adopted a forward guidance framework with the
intent of clarifying its policy reaction function and thus “give confidence to businesses
and households that policy will not be tightened until there is material reduction in
economic slack” (Charlie Bean, Deputy Governor of BOE for monetary policy). The
BOE’s forward guidance is conditional on the unemployment rate reaching a threshold
of 7 percent.
2.3 Euro Area
Following Lehman’s collapse, the spread between unsecured interbank deposit rates
(EURIBOR) and overnight indexed swap (OIS) rates at the three-month maturity
peaked at 200 basis points in the euro area. In response, on October 8, 2008 the ECB
cut its key policy rate by 50 basis points, part of a coordinated effort with several
major central banks, including the Fed, the BOE and the BOJ. Soon after, the ECB
announced several important innovations in its operational procedures. Giannone
4
The UK APF was actually announced in January of 2009 when the UK Treasury authorized
the BOE to buy up to £50 billion of “high quality private assets” to “increase the availability of
corporate credit by reducing the illiquidity of the underlying instruments” . Because Treasury would
finance these purchases through the sale of short-term gilts, they would not constitute quantitative
easing. Real quantitative easing, was introduced in March of 2009 with the announcement of the
£75 billion APF.
5
This limit on the purchases of private sector assets had been £50 billion, but was reduced in
November 2011, following an exchange of letters between the Governor and the Chancellor.
7
et al. (2011) discuss the ECB’s actions at this time in detail. Starting in 2009,
the strains from the Great Recession, and the costs that governments faced to bail
out their insolvent banking systems, began to cause euro-area sovereign debt spreads
to increase, and eventually led to questions about the sustainability of the single
currency area.
The ECB’s actions were guided by the limitations placed on it by the Lisbon Treaty
which prohibits the Eurosystem from conducting purchases of sovereign debt that are
interpreted as sovereign bailouts (Article 125) or monetary financing (Article 123).
Asset purchases, the magnitude of which are practically negligible, have been therefore
conducted with the objective of addressing market dysfunctions and repairing the
transmission mechanism of monetary policy. The ECB introduced the Securities
Market Programme (SMP) in May 2010 and the Outright Monetary Transaction
(OMT) program in August 2012 to purchase euro-area sovereign debt. Because these
programs are sterilized, they technically do not constitute monetary easing. It is
noteworthy that the OMT has not been activated so far. The ECB also introduced
in 2009 and 2011 two Covered Bond Purchase Programmes (CBPP1 and CBPP2) to
buy covered bonds across the Euro Area in both primary and secondary markets.
In addition, the ECB introduced a number of new measures within its regular mon-
etary policy framework. First, the ECB adopted in October 2008 a fixed rate/full
allotment (FRFA) tender procedure in its monetary policy operations, which is cur-
rently supposed to be maintained till mid-2015. This measure helped to stabilize the
banking sector at a time of significant stress by deferring to its counterparties the de-
cision on the quantity of liquidity to be provided. Second, the ECB expanded its list
of eligible collateral, for example by reducing the rating threshold for certain securi-
ties and by allowing National Central Banks (NCBs) to accept as collateral additional
performing credit claims, provided the NCBs retained the credit risk associated with
8
such transactions. Third, the ECB increased the number and variety of Eurosystem
longer-term refinancing operations (LTROs). In normal times, financial institutions
borrow from the Eurosystem through regular open market operations with maturi-
ties of 7-days (Main Refinancing Operations, MRO) or 3-months LTROs. Over time,
the ECB has introduced special 1-, 6-, 12-, 24- and 36-month operations. In 2009,
the ECB conducted three 1-year LTROs, with the first 1-year LTRO eliciting e442
billion in demand. In October 2011, the ECB reintroduced two 1-year LTROs, but
the second operation was replaced by the first 3-year LTRO. On December 2011, in
fact, the ECB introduced two 3-year LTROs that elicited an extraordinary demand.
Fourth, the ECB decreased the reserve ratio from 2 to 1 percent, effective January
18, 2012, which freed up over e100 billion.
Since 2008, the ECB has also announced several changes to its target rate, the
MRO rate. The rate was cut from 4.25 percent in early October 2008 to 1 percent by
May of 2009. Despite a short-lived reversal in 2011 when the MRO rate was increased
to 1.5 percent, the ECB has been lowering its target rate over the past two years.
The rate reached 25 basis points in November 2013.
6
2.4 Japan
The BOJ has experimented with unconventional policies since the late 1990s and
was the first major central bank to introduce a policy of quantitative easing (QEP)
as well as forward guidance. QEP was structured in three parts: a commitment
to maintain zero interest rates until deflation clearly ended (forward guidance); a
significant increase in the Bank’s balance sheet; and a change in the composition
of that balance sheet by increasing its outright purchases of longer-dated Japanese
6
The ECB only began providing some qualitative forward guidance in July 2013, a substantial
change in ECB communication, as both Draghi and his predecessor, Trichet, had stated that the
ECB would never pre-commit.
9
government securities. Overall in Japan, because many important measures were
introduced at the same time of the forward guidance, it is difficult to gauge the
effectiveness of this commitment. QEP was implemented initially from 2001 to 2006
and then again beginning in 2011 and with Abenomics. The initial foray of the BOJ
into quantitative easing policy was from March 2001 to March 2006. Japan faced low
economic growth, persistent deflation and a great number of non-performing loans in
its banking system left over from the first Asian financial crisis of 1997 and the dot-
com bubble that burst in 2000.
7
Initially, the BOJ increased the outstanding balance
of current accounts held at the BOJ from 4 to 5 trillion yen. Its initial outright
purchase pace of long-term government bonds was U400 billion per month. Over the
five years that the program was in place, the BOJ raised its current–account target
six times.
In 2006 and 2007 the BOJ allowed short-term bonds to roll-off in preparation for
raising rates, but in October of 2010 it announced another Asset Purchase Program
(APP). The APP was part of the Comprehensive Monetary Easing together with
a “virtually zero interest rate” policy and a commitment to maintain zero interest
rates until the BOJ judged that price stability (i.e. 1 percent inflation) was in sight.
The APP aimed at reducing term and risk premia through purchases of government
securities, corporate bonds, commercial paper, exchange-traded funds (ETFs), and
real estate investment trusts (REITs). Its size was initially set at U35 trillion, but
7
At the same time QEP provided the banking system with liquidity, the BOJ and Japan’s govern-
ment stepped up programs from the late 1990s designed to remove NPLs from bank balance sheets.
The government provided a blanket guarantee on deposits and enabled the Resolution and Collection
Corporation (RCC) to purchase non-performing loans and the Industrial Revitalization Corporation
of Japan (IRCJ) to purchase loans from those financial institutions that had been deemed to be
sound. In addition, in October 2002, the BOJ announced the Stock Purchasing Program in which
the Bank purchased stocks held by commercial banks. By the time the program ended in September
2004, the Bank held a total value of U2 trillion of equities purchased from Japanese banks. By the
summer of 2003 the BOJ was also purchasing asset-backed commercial paper and securities from
bank directly.
10
increased to U101 trillion by December 2012. On April 4, 2013, the BOJ announced
its Qualitative and Quantitative Easing in which it increased purchases of Japanese
government bonds (JGBs) to U50 trillion yen a year (from U20 trillion in 2012), and
it extended the average maturity from 3 to 7 years. In the same announcement the
BOJ committed to increase the monetary base at a pace of U60-70 trillion a year over
the next two years and it set an explicit two-year time horizon to achieve a 2 percent
inflation target.
3 Immediate Announcement Effects of Monetary
Policy News
For the different central banks, we list the monetary policy announcement days that
we consider in Tables 1-4, and we also report the times of these announcements, which
are important for our intraday analysis. Most announcements concern unconventional
monetary policy initiatives, though there were some changes in short-term policy
interest rates over this period. Most announcements consist of statements after policy
meetings, but some important speeches and other events are included as well. Our
goal is to study the financial market effects of these announcements.
We consider a large number of announcements, most of which were either not very
consequential, or largely anticipated. But there are several policy announcements that
came as big surprises, which is of course what we want for identification. Four good
examples are the BOE and FOMC announcements of Treasury purchase programs in
March 2009, the announcement of open-ended asset purchases by the BOJ on April
4, 2013, and the FOMC meeting of June 19, 2013, signalling an earlier-than-expected
end to LSAPs. We examine the effects of these announcements on government bond
11
yields in the country/currency area for which the announcement was made. Figure 1
plots the change in zero-coupon yields and forward rates of different maturities (the
forward rate yield curve) using daily government yield curve data bracketing each of
these announcements.
Looking at forward rates is useful, because under the expectations hypothesis of
the term structure, these should be equal to expected future short rates. So this can
give us an idea of whether a downward shift in the yield curve owes to the central
bank effectively committing to keep rates at zero for longer than had been expected,
as prescribed by Eggertsson and Woodford (2003), or to falling term premia. A fall in
yields that is concentrated in forward rates two or three years hence could potentially
be interpreted as either pushing back the expected timing of liftoff from the zero lower
bound, or as a drop in the term premia. But a fall in yields that is concentrated in
forward rates five years and beyond is only plausibly interpretable as a decline in term
premia—a central bank cannot provide credible forward guidance at these horizons.
Indeed, any effect of monetary policy accommodation on long-term expectations of
future short rates should be for them to go up, as a more accommodative stance of
policy raises perceptions of steady-state inflation (G¨urkaynak et al., 2005a).
The March 2009 announcement by the BOE and the April 2013 announcement by
the BOJ both produced the largest declines in long-term rates, including big drops
in forward rates ten to twenty years hence. For these two announcements, it seems
clear that the decline in rates owes to a fall in the term premium. The asset purchase
program announced by the Fed in 2009 was explicitly limited to bonds in the two-
to-ten-year sector and so it is natural that these rates fell the most. But forward
rates five-years-ahead and beyond dropped sharply, and again declining term premia
seems very likely to be the main explanation. Just to get an idea of scale, the drop in
ten-year yields on the day of the March 2009 FOMC meeting was the largest one-day
12
absolute change in ten-year yields from 1987 to the time of writing.
The June 2013 FOMC meeting was an example of a surprise going in the opposite
direction, and is significant to policy going forward for that very reason. As investors
read the announcement and press conference as signaling an earlier-than-expected
end to LSAPs, they brought forward their expected timing of the onset of monetary
policy tightening and drove term premia higher. The shift in forward rates was a
bit more front-loaded than for the other three announcements considered in Figure
1. At the same time, interest rate uncertainty, as measured by options, increased
substantially. That seems consistent with a rebound in term premia. A variety of
other pieces of monetary policy news in the US around this time, such as Chairman
Bernanke’s testimony to Congress on May 22, 2013, produced similar effects.
Besides the fact that these announcement produced large shifts in forward rates
at the five-year-ahead horizon and beyond, there are two other reasons for thinking
that much of these yield curve movements represent shifts in term premia. First,
surveys have shown no evidence of long-horizon expectations of future short rates
moving much, except that long run inflation expectations have moved up recently in
Japan, which makes the presumptive term premium shift in that country even bigger.
Second, in these and other episodes, it was the specific securities that the central bank
intended to buy whose prices moved the most (see for example D’Amico et al. (2012)
and Joyce and Tong (2012)).
8
3.1 Pass-through beyond government bond yields
From these events, we take it as given that central banks are capable of producing
meaningful immediate effects on their own government bond yields, that probably
8
Term premia shifts can be further decomposed into duration risk premia and local supply effects,
see for example D’Amico et al. (2012) and Cahill et al. (2013).
13
mainly reflect shifts in term premia. The remainder of the paper seeks to measure
the pass-through into other asset prices, and also the persistence of these effects. We
can measure monetary policy surprises as intraday changes in government bond yields
right around the announcement time. For the US, this is the first principal component
of the change in yields for two-, five- and ten- and thirty-year Treasury futures.
9
For
the UK, it is the change in long gilt futures yields. For Japan, it is the change
in ten-year JGB futures yields. Given the unique circumstances facing the euro
area, we measure ECB monetary policy surprises somewhat differently as intraday
changes in cash-market spreads between yields on Italian ten-year government bonds
and their German counterparts. More on this in subsection 3.2 below. In all cases,
the intraday window is either from 15 minutes before to 15 minutes after (narrow
window), or from 15 minutes before to 1 hour 45 minutes after (wide window). All
monetary policy surprises are normalized to be of 25 basis point magnitude, and
all surprises are signed so that a positive surprise represents an easing of monetary
policy—the surprise is minus the relevant yield change.
The idea of measuring monetary policy surprises directly from asset prices was also
considered by G¨urkaynak et al. (2005b) who used near-term money market futures
quotes to measure the effect of monetary policy announcements on expectations of
the path of policy during the period of conventional monetary policy. Wright (2012)
extended this to using Treasury futures during the recent period of unconventional
monetary policy, and the same approach is used in Glick and Leduc (2012). But in
this paper we are applying the idea to the announcements from all four central banks.
Having obtained a measure of monetary policy surprises, for each central bank we
9
For all government bond futures, yield changes are approximated by dividing price changes by
minus the modified duration of the cheapest-to-deliver security.
14
consider regressions of the form:
y
t
= βM P S
t
+ ε
t
(1)
where y
t
denotes a yield change or asset price returns in a daily or intradaily window
bracketing the announcement and MP S
t
denotes the monetary policy surprise. The
financial asset prices consist of intradaily data on bond, stock and exchange rate
futures, combined with daily data on corporate bond yields, the MOVE index
10
and
euro-area sovereign yields, as listed in Table 5. The regressions are run without an
intercept. Our sample period goes from around the start of the era of unconventional
policy through June 2013; the data start in January 2007 for Japan, in August 2007
for the ECB, in November 2008 for the Fed, and in January 2009 for the BOE.
The results using the narrow window to measure both the monetary policy sur-
prises and the intradaily changes on the left hand side of equation (1) are shown in
Table 6. The corresponding results using the wide window are reported in Table 7.
Here and throughout this paper, we estimate regressions by robust regression to avoid
excessive influence of outliers.
11
In most cases, OLS estimation would give similar
results, but there are some parameters where limiting the influence of outliers makes
a substantial difference.
Using the narrow window (Table 6), for the Fed, BOE or BOJ, the expansionary
monetary policy surprise significantly lowers corporate bond yields, but the fall in
corporate bond yields is less than one-for-one. That in turn means that the yield
spreads of corporate bonds over their sovereign counterparts widens, but of course
what matters for economic activity is the rate, not the spread. Still it is important to
be clear that the risk premium which is potentially decreasing is the term premium on
10
The MOVE index is an index of options-implied interest rate volatility.
11
We use the robust regression M-estimator of Huber (1981) with the bisquare weighting function.
15
government bonds,
12
not the risk premium component of the corporate-government
bond spread.
13
The expansionary monetary policy shock significantly raises domestic stock prices
in the US and the euro area, but not in the UK or Japan. This is consistent with
the existing literature. Rosa (2012) found that UK monetary policy shocks have
comparable effects on other fixed income markets to their US counterparts, but have
smaller effects on equity markets, and Arai (2013) found a similar result for Japan.
An expansionary monetary policy shock by the Fed, BOE or BOJ causes the
domestic currency to depreciate significantly. But for the ECB, the effect goes in the
opposite direction. The euro-area expansionary monetary policy surprise leads the
euro to appreciate significantly, and also causes German bond and euro-area corporate
bond yields to rise significantly, presumably because the surprise lessened safe-haven
flows into bunds and promoted financial stability and confidence in the survival of
European monetary union. The euro-area expansionary monetary policy surprises
causes the pound to appreciate slightly (but significantly) viz-a-viz the dollar and
causes Spanish sovereign yields to fall sharply.
Also, we find that monetary policy shocks in one currency area affect bond yields in
other currency areas, but the spillovers go mainly from US monetary policy surprises
to non-US yields rather than the other way round. For example, the US monetary
policy surprise that lowers the ten-year US yield by 25 basis points reduces German
and UK ten-year yields by 11 and 10 basis points respectively. The UK monetary
12
Traditionally, we think of this as not embodying any default risk, but rather just the risk of
capital loss if the bonds are sold prior to maturity. Recent events in both Europe and the United
States may have made the traditional assumption less plausible.
13
Most of the asset prices that we consider relate to large and liquid markets, such as stock and
bond futures or foreign exchange. But for the corporate bond indices, there is a potential concern
that prices may be stale. We investigated estimating equation (1) with two-day changes in corporate
bond yields on the left-hand-side (changes from the day before the announcement to the day after).
Coefficient estimates were generally bigger than using one-day changes, but the results were not
qualitatively different.
16
policy surprise has a smaller but significant effect on US ten-year yields, and the
euro and Japanese monetary policy surprises have no significant effect on US ten-
year yields. This asymmetry has been found in sample periods covering conventional
monetary policy by researchers including Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2005), though
G¨urkaynak and Wright (2011) found that some non-US conventional monetary policy
announcements also affect the US yield curve. Fratzscher et al. (2013) provide a
detailed study of the effects of US unconventional monetary policy announcements
and actions on global asset prices and portfolio flows.
The effects of monetary policy shocks on exchange rates and foreign interest rates
are very important, as they represent unintended policy spillovers. Monetary policy
easing by the Fed has offsetting effects on the rest of the world; it causes other
currencies to appreciate viz-a-viz the dollar, but at the same time it reduces longer-
term interest rates in other countries. Conversely, monetary policy easing by non-US
central banks causes the dollar to appreciate, and may cause longer-term US interest
rates to fall, but we find this latter effect only for UK easings, and even in this case
it is small.
Results are generally similar using the wide window (Table 7). However, there
are some differences. The estimated effect of an expansionary UK monetary policy
surprise on the exchange value of the pound is smaller in the wide window than in
the narrow window. The effect of an expansionary Japanese monetary policy surprise
on stock prices is significantly negative in the wide window. In this case, we suspect
that moving to the wider window has contaminated the monetary policy surprise with
other shocks, which is the downside of using a wider window.
17
3.2 Euro-area monetary policy shocks
Our measurement of monetary policy shocks in the euro area is different from that
for the other central banks. It might seem more natural to measure euro-area mon-
etary policy surprises from intraday changes in German bond yields, as this would
be more directly parallel to the treatment of the US, UK and Japan. However, the
actions of the ECB over this particular period, as discussed the previous in section,
were clearly aimed at intra-euro area sovereign spreads, not at the level of German
interest rates. ECB President Draghi has emphasized the special importance of
intra-euro area spreads in the transmission mechanism of monetary policy, under the
unusual circumstances of the last few years. Indeed, actions that succeded in lower-
ing sovereign spreads tended to drive German yields up. Thus, measuring monetary
policy from German yields alone would result in the perverse conclusion that these
actions, such as the OMT announcement, represented an attempt by the ECB to
tighten financial conditions. Intra-euro area sovereign spreads reflect default risk and
default risk premia that are normally thought of as being separate from monetary
policy. But the special circumstances of the euro area in the last few years—where
monetary policy was aimed at reducing default risk and risk premia—mean that it is
appropriate to measure monetary policy differently. Consequently it is not surprising
that monetary policy had quite different effects in the euro area and elsewhere.
3.3 Comparison with Conventional Monetary Policy
Our analysis in this paper applies only to the period of unconventional monetary
policy. In this subsection we compare our findings with those of other studies that
apply to the earlier period of conventional monetary policy. On pre-ZLB US data,
G¨urkaynak et al. (2005b) estimated that a 25 basis point surprise reduction in the
18
federal funds rate caused ten-year yields to fall by about 10 basis points and stock
prices to rise by about 2 percentage points. In our sample we find that a 25 basis point
surprise reduction in the ten-year yield (without any change in the federal funds rate)
causes stock prices to rise by 0.7 percentage points. The pre-ZLB and ZLB eras are
thus estimated to be quite different. Clearly, monetary policy is working at different
points on the term structure: It has the largest effects on short-term interest rates
in conventional monetary policy, but the largest effects on long-term interest rates in
unconventional policy. But, in addition, a given decline in long-term interest rates
caused by monetary policy had a much larger effect on stock prices in the conventional
monetary policy period than it does with unconventional policy. According to the
estimates of G¨urkaynak et al. (2005b), in the pre-ZLB period, the federal funds rate
would have to be cut by about 60 basis points to lower ten-year yields by 25 basis
points, and this should in turn boost stock prices by about 5 percentage points. Our
estimates over the ZLB period are much smaller.
For the UK, we find no statistically significant effect of unconventional-period
monetary policy surprises on stock prices; earlier studies from the pre-ZLB period
found that surprise Bank of England easings had a significant positive effect on stock
prices, although the magnitude was smaller than pre-ZLB estimates for the US (see,
e.g. Bredin et al. (2007)).
We estimate that unconventional monetary policy surprise easings cause corporate
credit spreads to increase (corporate yields fall, but by less than their sovereign coun-
terparts). With conventional monetary policy, the empirical evidence indicates that
surprise reductions in short-term policy interest rates cause corporate credit spreads
to fall (see, e.g. Cenesizoglu and Essid (2012)).
In relation to the stock market and corporate yields, we thus find some evidence
that while unconventional monetary policy has effects on these other markets, the
19
ZLB constraint makes it less powerful than conventional monetary policy. Kiley
(2013a,b) also reached this conclusion. On the other hand, the estimated effect on the
foreign exchange value of the dollar of a monetary policy surprise that lowers ten-year
Treasury yields is roughly similar with conventional and unconventional monetary
policy (Glick and Leduc, 2013).
3.4 Econometric Comment
The concerns with window size in estimating equation (1) have motivated some re-
searchers, such as Kiley (2013b) and Gilchrist et al. (2013) to consider an instrumental
variables (IV) strategy. This methodology involves estimating the regression using
daily changes, but instrumenting the daily change in yields on the right-hand-side with
an intraday change in yields around the monetary policy announcement. However,
there is a strong presumption in finance that the serial correlation of yield changes
in adjacent windows is small.
14
Given this presumption, the population expectation
of the daily yield change conditional on the intradaily yield change should be equal
to the intraday yield change. Since an IV estimator can be interpreted as the OLS
estimator, replacing the right-hand-side variable with its projection onto the instru-
ment, this means that the IV estimator should be the same in large samples as just
running an OLS regression with the intraday yield change on the right-hand-side. In
small samples they will be different, but that is because there happens to be some
serial correlation in yield changes in a particular sample. Since we think that any
serial correlation in yield changes is best thought of as a “fluke”, we prefer not to
rely on it, and consequently just run the regression in equation (1) by OLS, with
intradaily changes as the right-hand-side variable. If the intraday window includes
14
If a yield change in one part of the day is serially correlated with a yield change in a later part
of the day, then it implies a massive failure of efficient markets.
20
shocks other than the monetary policy surprise, then this method will fail, but so will
the IV strategy. If this is the concern, then identification through heteroskedasticity
is the appropriate econometric technique, and we consider this in section 5 below.
3.5 Effects of Different Types of Announcements
Generally in this paper, we are examining the composite effects of unconventional
monetary policy, without decomposing it into forward guidance, asset purchases,
policies to relieve strains in particular markets and so on. But in this subsection we
attempt to break out the effects of different types of announcements. We adopt two
methods to do this.
3.5.1 Judgmental Classification of Announcements
The first method that we consider is to split monetary policy announcements into
different types. For the Fed, we split announcements into those that we view as pre-
dominantly containing news about LSAPs and the other announcements, as marked
in Table 1. There are of course many announcements that have elements of both,
which is the limitation of this method, but we nevertheless attempt to put each an-
nouncement into one of these categories.
15
Then we estimate equation (1) using the
narrow window for LSAP and other announcement days separately. The results are
reported in Table 8. The monetary policy shock has a larger effect on two-year yields
on non-LSAP days than on LSAP days, which makes sense because forward rate guid-
ance is the most important unconventional policy other than asset purchases, and its
effects should be concentrated on the short end of the yield curve. LSAP announce-
ments have significant effects on corporate bond yields and the stock market, whereas
15
Our classification of FOMC announcements is similar to, but not the same as, that of Gilchrist
et al. (2013).
21
non-LSAP announcements do not.
The same approach applies to the other central banks. For the BOE and BOJ, we
split announcements into those that were primarily concerned with the asset purchase
programmes and other announcements, as marked in Tables 2 and 4. For the ECB,
we split announcements into those based on bond purchases, those based on LTROs,
and other announcements, as marked in Table 3.
Tables 9, 10 and 11 report the results from estimating equation (1) for these
different announcement types for the BOE, ECB and BOJ, respectively.
For the BOE (Table 9), monetary policy shocks are estimated to a have significant
effect on the exchange rate both on asset purchase and other announcements, but the
magnitude of the response is larger on asset purchase days. Monetary policy shocks
are estimated to have a significant effect on corporate bond yields on asset purchase
days, but not on other days.
For the ECB (Table 10), bond purchase and LTRO announcements both reduce
Italian and Spanish yields and boost stock prices, and all of these effects are statis-
tically significant. Other announcements reduce Italian yields, raise German yields,
and have a smaller but significant positive effect on stock prices.
For the BOJ (Table 11), the asset purchase announcements are estimated to have a
larger effect on the dollar-yen exchange rate and on stock prices than other monetary
policy announcements.
Broadly, our results in Tables 8-11 suggest that—to the extent that we can sep-
arate unconventional monetary policy announcements into those that concern as-
set purchases and those that do not—the pass-through from the former is generally
larger.
22
3.5.2 Two dimensions of monetary policy measured from the yield curve
The second method that we consider for examining the effects of different kinds of
central bank announcements is applicable to the US alone, because this is the only
country for which our intradaily data gives us yields at different maturities (Table 5).
For the US, we measure a two-dimensional surprise on monetary policy announcement
days: the first two principal components of the change in two-, five- and ten- and
thirty-year Treasury futures yields. We then consider regressions of the form:
y
t
= β
1
MP S
1t
+ β
2
MP S
2t
+ ε
t
(2)
where M P S
1t
and M P S
2t
denote the two kinds of monetary policy surprises. The
results are reported in Table 12 (using the narrow window). The first monetary
policy surprise raises all rates, but especially at the long end. We interpret this as
an expansionary LSAP shock. The second monetary policy surprise rotates the yield
curve, pushing short rates down and long rates up. We interpret this as forward
guidance shock. The first monetary policy shock has large and significant effects;
it drives all yields including corporate yields down, causes the dollar to depreciate,
and stock prices to rise. The second monetary policy shock rotates the Treasury
yield curve, but has no significant effect on stock prices, corporate bond yields or the
foreign exchange value of the dollar.
However, an expansionary value of the second (non-LSAP) monetary policy shock
on the MOVE index is significantly negative. As forward guidance is the most signifi-
cant non-LSAP element to US monetary policy, this suggests an important mechanism
through which forward guidance may be effective, that has received little emphasis in
the literature. Forward guidance may not only lower the expected path of monetary
policy, but it may also reduce uncertainty about future policy, and thereby lower term
23
premia
16
(see Akkaya (2014) for further discussion of this possibility).
3.6 Asymmetry
It is possible that surprise tightenings and easings of monetary policy might have
different effects on asset prices. The possibility has been investigated in the context of
conventional monetary policy (e.g. Kuttner (2001)) and little evidence for asymmetry
has been found. It is a bit difficult to investigate in the context of unconventional
monetary policy because most (but not all) surprises have been easings.
Nonetheless, to attempt to investigate the possibility, we augmented equation (1)
with an interaction with a sign dummy, considering the specification:
y
t
= β
1
MP S
t
+ β
2
MP S
t
1(MP S
t
> 0) + ε
t
(3)
Our focus is on β
2
. Estimates of the coefficients in equation (3) are reported for some
asset prices in Table 13 (using the narrow window). In interpreting these results,
recall that a positive value of MP S
t
refers to a surprise easing. In most cases β
2
is not
statistically significant. But it is statistically significant for the effects of monetary
policy surprises on stock returns in the US and the UK (at the 10 percent level in
the latter case). The interpretation of the estimated coefficient is that the boost to
stocks from an expansionary monetary policy shock is larger in magnitude than the
negative impact on stocks of a surprise monetary policy tightening.
16
Term premia are important (and time-varying) even for fairly short-term interest rates (Piazzesi
and Swanson, 2008)
24
3.7 Crisis and non-crisis subsamples
One might wonder if the effects of monetary policy shocks were different during the
acute phase of the global financial crisis. Models of market segmentation suggest that
asset purchases should be particularly effective in lowering the prices of the assets
being purchased when arbitrage capital is scarce and markets are not functioning
normally (Vayanos and Vila, 2009; Greenwood and Vayanos, forthcoming). Multiple
equilibria stories are also more persuasive in times of crises. IMF (2013) suggest
that asset purchases may be most effective at times of crises. However, this paper
is mainly concerned with estimation of pass-through—given an x basis point drop
in domestic government bond yields caused by unconventional monetary policy, we
study the spillover effects on other asset prices. This kind of pass-through might be
smallest when arbitrage capital is scarcest.
To investigate the question empirically, we estimated equation (1) using the narrow
window for all four central banks, splitting the sample into subsamples for 2008 and
2009 and other years. We view these as crisis and non-crisis subsamples. Coefficient
estimates are reported in Table 14. For the Fed and BOE, the main difference between
the crisis and non-crisis subsamples is that the standard errors tend to be bigger in the
latter, because all the big surprises happened in 2008 and 2009. There is no consistent
pattern of pass-through being larger or smaller in the two subsamples. For the ECB,
things are quite different. The standard errors are larger in the 2008/2009 subsample
and pass-through into corporate yields, stock prices and the foreign exchange value
of the euro is significant only in the other subsample. But this is not surprising—
although 2008/2009 was the peak of the global financial crisis, the euro-specific crisis
came later. For the ECB, the largest monetary policy surprises were clearly in 2011
and 2012. For the BOJ, there were relatively large monetary policy surprises both
25
during 2008/2009 and at other times (before and since). However, the significant
effect of BOJ monetary policy surprises on the foreign exchange value of the yen was
found only during the non-2008/2009 subsample.
4 Persistence
The method described in section 3 is intended to measure the immediate effect of
monetary policy shocks on asset prices. It is obviously important to know how per-
sistent these effects are. The normal presumption in the event study literature is
that the effects are long-lasting (Fama et al., 1969). But there are several natural
mechanisms that might cause the effects of unconventional monetary policy surprises
to wear off over time including:
(1) Quantitative easing may make the economy recover faster than would otherwise
have been the case, ultimately driving interest rates back up.
(2) Quantitative easing may induce more corporate issuance of long-term bonds
(Stein, 2012), which would in turn also tend to push long-term rates higher.
(3) Frictions may make arbitrage capital slow-moving—and thus better able to
offset the impact of preferred habitat investors in the long-run than in the
short-run (Duffie, 2010; Mitchell et al., 2007).
(4) Many of the important unconventional monetary policy surprises took place at
a time when financial markets were impaired, and so effects of asset purchases
on bond yields may have been particularly large. As arbitrage capital returned
to financial markets, the effects would have got smaller.
26
(5) Some part of the effect of unconventional monetary policy surprises was to lower
the near-term expected path of the federal funds rate. But, in the absence of
any further news, the impact of this shift on the ten-year yield mechanically
disappears with the passage of time.
Lou et al. (2013) document that the increase in Treasury supply associated with
new auctions has an impact on bond prices, but that it wears off within days. Casual
empiricism indicates that the effect of unconventional monetary policy announce-
ments on asset prices does not wear off that fast. At same time, some tendency for
the effects of policy shocks to weak off is arguably implicit in the results of existing
studies, at least for the US. Gagnon et al. (2011) add up the announcement effects
of LSAP announcements from November 2008 to November 2009 on ten-year yields,
and find that it comes to 91 basis points. These announcements were essentially
complete surprises, and so this is a natural way to assess their immediate impact. It
is harder to measure the effects of FOMC actions since November 2009 on Treasury
yields, because news about these did not come out in clear surprise announcements.
But Li and Wei (2013) argue that as of 2012, all the LSAPs jointly had lowered
ten-year Treasury yields by 100 basis points, and that seems a reasonable calibra-
tion. However, if these numbers are to be reconciled, then either the FOMC actions
since November 2009 had minimal effects
17
, or else the 91 basis points of easing in
2008-2009 must have worn off, at least in part.
An approach for assessing persistence more formally is to use a VAR in daily
asset price data. We briefly summarize the econometric method, discussed in more
detail in Wright (2012). We assume that a px1 vector of yields, observed at the daily
17
There is plenty of evidence against this; for example D’Amico et al. (2012) estimate that the
second LSAP program lowered ten-year yields by 55 basis points.
27
frequency, Y
t
, has the reduced form VAR representation
A(L)Y
t
= µ + ε
t
(4)
where ε
t
denote the reduced form forecast errors. We further assume that these re-
duced form errors can be related to a set of underlying structural shocks
ε
t
= Σ
p
i=1
R
i
η
i,t
(5)
where η
i,t
is the ith structural shock, R
i
is a px1 vector, and the structural shocks
are independent of each other and over time. The monetary policy shock is ordered
first, for notational convenience only.
We can then regress the reduced form errors onto the monetary policy shocks
identified from intradaily data in section 3. This immediately gives us an estimate
of R
1
and allows us to estimate the VAR. Inference can then done using the bias-
adjusted bootstrap of Kilian (1998).
We applied this method to data from the United States, United Kingdom, euro
area, and Japan and fitted a VAR to daily data on two- and ten-year government
bond yields and corporate yields as listed in Table 5. For the euro area, we fitted
a VAR to daily data on ten-year Italian, Spanish and French spreads over their
German counterparts, ten-year German bond yields, and corporate bond yields as
listed in Table 5. In all cases the number of VAR lags was determined by the Bayes
Information Criterion. The impulse responses function estimates and 90 percent
bootstrap confidence intervals applying the method to the US, UK, euro area and
Japan are reported in Figures 2-5, respectively.
28
For the US, UK and Japan (Figures 2, 3 and 5), the effect of the monetary
policy shock on ten-year government bond yields and on corporate bond yields is
significant at short horizons. The persistence of the effects is not precisely estimated,
but the point estimates indicate that the effects “wear off,” but do so fairly slowly. For
Japan, the effect on two-year yields is estimated to be very small, and not statistically
significant, likely because two-year yields have been clearly constrained by the zero
lower bound in Japan for the last few years.
For the euro area (Figure 4), the expansionary monetary policy shock lowers Ital-
ian, French and Spanish government bond spreads over their German counterparts,
and the effect remains statistically significant for some time. The expansionary mon-
etary policy shock is also estimated to raise German and corporate bond yields, but
these impulse responses are only significant at the shortest horizons.
5 Identification Through Heteroskedasticity
The methodologies in the last two sections rely on the window being sufficiently small
that the monetary policy announcement is the only shock within this window. This
may be a reasonable approximation if the window is very short. But monetary policy
announcements in the last few years have been complicated and may take time for
markets to digest.
18
And they are coupled with press conferences that come a bit
later. That motivates a winder window, which in turn makes it likely that other
shocks will come in that contaminate the monetary policy surprise.
An alternative approach is given by identification through heteroskedasticity. This
does not require us to assume that monetary policy surprises are directly measurable.
18
For example, the word count of FOMC statements has on average gone from around 200 in
2008 to over 600 in 2013. The more recent statements have addressed the size and composition of
LSAPs, calendar and forward guidance, exit principles, etc.
29
Instead, it uses daily data and posits that in the structural VAR model given by
equations (4) and (5), the structural monetary policy shock η
1,t
has mean zero and
variance σ
2
1
on announcement days, and variance σ
2
0
on all other days, while all other
structural shocks are identically distributed on all days. The identifying assumption
is that σ
2
0
6= σ
2
1
. We just need to know that there is something special about monetary
policy days, not that we are actually able to measure the surprise. Suppose that there
are T
0
non-announcement days and T
1
announcement days. Let Σ
0
and Σ
1
denote
the variance-covariance matrices of reduced form errors ε
t
on non-announcement and
announcement days, respectively. Clearly,
Σ
1
Σ
0
= R
1
R
0
1
σ
2
1
R
1
R
0
1
σ
2
0
= R
1
R
0
1
(σ
2
1
σ
2
0
)
This allows R
1
to be identified. Without loss of generality, we adopt the normalization
that σ
2
1
σ
2
0
= 1, as R
1
R
0
1
and σ
2
1
σ
2
0
are not separately identified. The econometric
strategy is to estimate the VAR and construct the sample variance-covariance matrices
of residuals on non-announcement and announcement days,
ˆ
Σ
0
and
ˆ
Σ
1
, respectively.
Then the parameters in the vector R
1
can be estimated by solving the minimum
distance problem:
ˆ
R
1
= arg min
R
1
[vech(
ˆ
Σ
1
ˆ
Σ
0
) vech(R
1
R
0
1
)]
0
[
ˆ
V
0
+
ˆ
V
1
]
1
[vech(
ˆ
Σ
1
ˆ
Σ
0
) vech(R
1
R
0
1
)]
where
ˆ
V
0
and
ˆ
V
1
are estimates of the variance-covariance matrices of vech(
ˆ
Σ
0
) and
vech(
ˆ
Σ
1
). Armed with
ˆ
R
1
, estimates of the impulse responses can then be traced
out.
We fitted exactly the same VARs to daily data as in the previous section, with the
lag length again determined by the Bayes Information Criterion. We then applied
30
identification through heteroskedasticity to measure the dynamic effects of monetary
policy shocks on other asset prices, taking the measure of monetary policy as being
ten-year government bond yields in the US, UK and Japan, and the spread between
Italian and German bond yields for in euro area. For the Fed, the BOE and BOJ, we
normalize the monetary policy shock to lower ten-year government bond yields by 25
basis points; for the ECB, we normalize the monetary policy shock to lower Italian
bond yields by 25 basis points.
Table 15 reports the results of tests of the hypothesis that Σ
0
= Σ
1
(announcement
and non-announcement days are identical) and of the hypothesis that the difference
between the two variance-covariance matrices can be factored in the form R
1
R
0
1
(the
data can be well characterized by a single monetary policy shock) for all four currency
areas. Bootstrap p-values are also included. Identification through heteroskedasticity
requires the first hypothesis to be rejected and the second to be accepted.
For the US and euro area, the hypothesis that the announcement and non-
announcement days are identical is decisively rejected, which is of course essential
to identification through heteroskedasticity. For the UK, the results of this test are
borderline with a p-value of 5.2 percent. For Japan, the test fails to reject, mean-
ing that the identification is weak. Arai (2013) gives a detailed application of the
identification-through-heteroskedasticity method to Japan, addressing the issue of
weak identification. He finds that identification is helped by considering a subset of
especially important monetary policy announcements.
The hypothesis of a one-dimensional monetary policy shock is not rejected for any
of the four currency areas.
For our set of announcement days, we can only be confident in identification
through heteroskedasticity working well for the US and the euro area. We thus
report impulse responses for the US and euro area alone. These are given in Figures
31
6 and 7, respectively.
The confidence intervals in Figures 6 and 7 are very wide. For the US (Figure 6),
the effect on corporate bond yields is significant, but only for a short time. Likewise,
for the euro area (Figure 7), the effect of the monetary policy on Italian-German and
Spanish-German sovereign bond spreads is significant, but only at short horizons,
while the shock has no significant effect on any other yields or spreads in the VAR,
at any horizon.
6 Discussion
The evidence from the last three sections points to monetary policy shocks having
substantial impacts on government bond yields which in turn pass through to other
asset prices, although to varying extents.
From the view-point of conventional asset pricing theory, the effects of monetary
policy shocks on government bond yields are surprising. Models with preferred habi-
tat investors—such as Modigliani and Sutch (1966, 1967) and, more recently, Vayanos
and Vila (2009) and Greenwood and Vayanos (forthcoming)—can go some way to ex-
plain why asset purchase announcements have very material effects of bond yields.
But in these preferred habitat models, and also in the empirical work of Hamilton
and Wu (2012), LSAPs are viewed as influencing yields by reducing the supply of
government bonds in the market.
A potential issue with this explanation is that there are other factors that pro-
duce large shifts in the effective supply of government bonds, and in this story they
should all have comparable effects on yields. One example is government bond
issuance—the rising issuance of US Treasuries coupled with the deliberate policy of
the Treasury to increase the maturity of outstanding debt has been a force of larger
32
magnitude than the Fed’s LSAPs and of opposite sign. If we think that LSAPs low-
ered ten-year Treasury yields by 100 basis points (Li and Wei, 2013), and we think of
all shifts in effective government bond supply as equivalent, then Treasury issuance
must have raised ten-year Treasury yields by at least 200 basis points. If so, then
notwithstanding safe-haven flows into Treasuries, it may seem a bit surprising that
Treasury yields have remained so low.
But it may be that central bank announcements about LSAPs have effects over
and above the direct effects of reducing the supply of bonds in the market. Arguably,
they are signaling that they will expand asset purchases and other programs as much
as needed to drive term premia and risk premia down, and to restore financial stability.
If so, the credible signal is perhaps itself enough to drive yields down. The case
for this seems especially clear for Europe. One can argue that there are multiple
equilibria, as in the model of Jeanne (2012). In one equilibrium, default is likely
and sovereign bond risk premia are high, ensuring an elevated probability of default.
In the other equilibrium, default is unlikely and the risk premia are low. Central
bank purchases—or even just the credible threat of such purchases—may have been
enough to switch the euro zone from the bad to the good equilibrium. Indeed, it is
hard to find any other explanation for the calming of concerns about the viability of
the single currency area around the time of the announcement of the OMT program
in 2012. This is especially so because OMT has been enormously effective despite
not involving any actual bond purchases (to date).
When a central banks buys long-term government bonds in a bid to boost de-
mand, the pass-through of the resulting decline in government bond yields to other
asset prices is of course essential to the policy accomplishing its goal. The Fed, BOE
and BOJ did not undertake government bond purchases with the aim of lowering gov-
ernment bond yields per se. Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgenson (2013) argue that
33
Fed purchases of Treasury had small spillover effects on other asset prices. Our read-
ing of the evidence as studied by us and other researchers is that there is considerable
pass-through, and we think that Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgenson substantially
understate its magnitude. That said, it stands to reason that if a central bank wants
to lower the interest rate on a particular security, the best way is to buy that par-
ticular security. For example, as noted by Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgenson, if
the goal is to lower MBS rates, buying MBS will have a bigger impact than buying
government bonds. However, there are operational and legal restrictions that limit
the capacity of central banks to buy private sector assets. The Fed could not op-
erationally have doubled the size of its “QE3” MBS purchase program, nor could it
legally have bought stocks or corporate bonds, or issued its own mortgages. Uncon-
ventional monetary policy seems to be at least somewhat effective in easing financial
conditions even at the zero lower bound, but the tools of unconventional policy are
limited.
6.1 Politics and unconventional monetary policy
There are also political economy issues associated with unconventional monetary pol-
icy. Central banks can act quickly in a crisis, and can take the blame for politically
unpopular decisions away from elected politicians, but monetary policy is not always
the best way of accomplishing objectives, and in any case this strategy imperils the
independence of central banks in the long run. There are elements of this dilemma
everywhere, but especially in Europe. The ECB always had the means to quell the
euro-zone crisis by expressing willingness to buy sovereign bonds in unlimited quan-
tities. Despite some protestations to the contrary, it cannot have been impossible,
or illegal, because they ultimately did it. Front-loading this and the other actions
34
that the ECB ultimately took would have spared Europe the worst of the economic
downturn. But it would also have taken the pressure off politicians for reforms that
were needed, or perceived to be needed. Also, it is easier for central banks to justify
unusual measures to politicians and the public once a crisis is clearly underway than
to do so pre-emptively. Considerations of this sort surely slowed the willingness of
the ECB to implement unconventional monetary policy.
6.2 Effects of Reversing Unconventional Policy
An important question going forward is the asset market effects of tapering and
eventually unwinding asset purchases and other aspects of unconventional monetary
policy. Our sample involves mostly surprise easings of policy, but at some point in
the future, there will be surprise policy tightenings. The natural presumption would
be that monetary policy tightening shocks will have similar effects, but of opposite
sign. The response of the markets to Chairman Bernanke’s testimony on May 22,
2013, and to the FOMC meeting on June 19, 2013, as discussed earlier, appears
broadly consistent with this presumption. But in subsection 3.6, we did find some
hint of an asymmetry whereby the stock market reaction to a surprise monetary policy
tightening is smaller than the reaction to a surprise monetary policy easing. One
can imagine reasons why some financial markets might potentially be more sensitive
to asset purchases than to their subsequent unwinding. Unconventional monetary
policy announcements can be interpreted as the central bank signaling that it will do
whatever it takes to ease financial conditions. But shrinking the balance sheet in the
future is unlikely to be part of a correspondingly deliberate and open-ended attempt
to tighten financial conditions. Still, the jury is still out on how tapering and the
eventual unwinding of unconventional monetary policy will impact financial markets.
35
The four central banks are likely to unwind unconventional policy at rather dif-
ferent times, which makes the cross-country spillover effects that we have estimated
especially important. For example, at the time of writing, it seems that the Federal
Reserve will seek to withdraw policy accommodation sooner than the ECB. We esti-
mate that a policy action that raises ten-year US yields by 50 basis points of raising
German ten-year yield by about 20 basis points, but also causes the euro to depreciate
relative to the dollar by roughly 2 percent (based on the estimates in Tables 6 and
7). This would imply a depreciation of the trade-weighted effective value of the euro
of about 0.4 percent. The interest rate and exchange rate spillovers work in opposite
directions, but on net this scenario would strike us as representing an effective tight-
ening of euro area financial conditions. If the ECB wanted to offset this spillover,
then their own monetary policy would have to become even more accommodative.
7 Conclusions
In the aftermath of the Great Recession, major central banks have driven short rates
to what is effectively the zero lower bound. It is a difficult situation which leaves
at least the potential for a vicious circle in which deflation with a zero nominal
interest rate drives real rates up, further adding to deflationary pressure (Williams
and Reifschneider, 2000). Moreover, nothing like this has happened on a global scale
since the Great Depression.
Alas, political constraints limit the ability of fiscal policy to boost demand, and
monetary policy is left as the only source of stimulus in the United States, the United
Kingdom and the euro zone. It is not a happy circumstance for central banks, yet
monetary policy is not impotent at the zero lower bound. In this paper, we have
studied the effects of unconventional monetary policy on bond yields, stock prices
36
and exchange rates for the Fed, BOE, ECB and BOJ, using common methodologies
with daily and especially intradaily asset price data. We find that these policies are
indeed effective in easing broad financial conditions—not just lowering government
bond yields—when policy rates are stuck at the zero lower bound. This appears to
work largely by reducing term premia, and indeed driving them negative. The flipside
of this is that the recovery, when it happens, will involve a substantial increase in
long-term yields, a foretaste of which was seen in the summer of 2013.
The pass-through from bond yields into other asset prices generally seems to be
bigger for the US than for other countries. There are also important cross-country
spillovers, but they are asymmetric—the effects of US monetary policy shocks on
non-US yields are larger than the other way round.
We have provided some comparison between the efficacy of asset purchases and
other unconventional monetary policies. We obtained no strong and consistent result—
perhaps reflecting the great difficulty of disentangling these two. However, at least
in the US, UK and Japan, the asset purchase announcements generally seem to have
more pass-through into asset prices other than government bond yields.
We have also attempted to estimate the persistence of effects of monetary policy
surprises. This is difficult to identify with much precision, but our point estimates
indicate that the effects wear off, although slowly. That implies that is not just the
stock of central bank purchases of securities that matters for financial conditions, but
also the flow.
Our focus in this paper has been on the effects of unconventional monetary policy
on asset prices. A separate but different research agenda is to measure the effects
of unconventional monetary policy on macroeconomic outcomes (see, for example,
Giannone et al. (2011) and Lenza et al. (2010)). This latter task is perhaps more
important, but also quite hard. We directly observe asset prices at the daily and
37
intradaily frequency, and so can measure the effects of news on these prices, as we
have done in this paper. Applying these techniques to macroeconomic outcomes
and expectations is more involved. However, the finding that the unconventional
monetary policies of the four central banks have eased broad financial conditions
means that they surely helped somewhat with respect to both reducing the output
gap and preventing inflation from falling too far below target.
38
Table 1: Dates and Times of US Monetary Policy Announcements
Year Day Time Description
(New York)
2008 10/8 7:00 FFTR decreased to 1.5%
10/29 14:15 FFTR decreased to 1%
11/25 8:15 Fed Announces Purchases of MBS
and Agency Bonds
12/1 13:45 Bernanke states Treasuries may be purchased
12/16 14:15 FOMC Meeting: FFTR decreased to 0–0.25%
2009 1/28 - 3/18 - 4/29 - 6/24 - 8/12 - 9/23 - 11/4 - 12/16 14:15 FOMC Meeting
2010 1/27 - 3/16 - 4/28 - 6/23 - 8/10 14:15 FOMC Meeting
8/27 10:00 Bernanke Speech at Jackson Hole
9/21 14:15 FOMC Meeting
10/15 8:15 Bernanke Speech at Boston Fed
11/3 - 12/14 14:15 FOMC Meeting
2011 1/26 - 3/15 - 4/27(12:30) - 6/22(12:30) - 8/9 14:15 FOMC Meeting
8/26 10:00 Bernanke Speech at Jackson Hole
9/21 - 11/2(12:30) - 12/13 14:15 FOMC Meeting
2012 1/25(12:30) - 3/13 - 4/25(12:30) - 6/20(12:30) - 8/1 14:15 FOMC Meeting
8/31 10:00 Bernanke Speech at Jackson Hole
9/13(12:30) - 10/24 - 12/12(12:30) 14:15 FOMC Meeting
2013 1/30 - 3/20(14:00) - 5/1(14:00) 14:15 FOMC Meeting
5/22 10:00 Bernanke Testimony
6/19 14:00 FOMC Meeting
Notes: Date only is an FOMC meeting, time is 14:15 unless otherwise indicated. Entries in bold
denote the announcements that we treat as LSAP announcements; all other announcements are
treated as non-LSAP.
39
Table 2: Dates and Times of UK Monetary Policy Announcements
Year Day Time Description
(London)
2008 10/8 12:00 MPC meeting, bank rate decreased to 4.5%
11/6 12:00 MPC meeting, bank rate decreased to 3%
12/4 12:00 MPC meeting, bank rate decreased to 2%
2009 1/8 12:00 MPC meeting, bank rate decreased to 1.5%
1/19 12:00 The chancellor of the Exchequer
announces the BOE will set up an APF
1/29 12:00 Asset Purchase Facility announcement
2/5 12:00 MPC meeting, rate decreased to 1%
2/11 12:00 Inflation report and press conference
give strong indication that QE is likely
3/5 12:00 APF announcement: £75 billion of Gilts, 5-25 years;
bank rate decreased to 0.5%
4/9 12:00 MPC meeting
5/7 12:00 APF extended to £125 billion
6/4 - 7/9 12:00 MPC meeting
8/6 12:00 APF extended to £175 billion, 3+ yrs maturity
9/10 - 10/8 12:00 MPC meeting
11/5 12:00 APF extended to £200 billion
12/10 12:00 MPC meeting
2010 1/7 12:00 MPC meeting
2/4 12:00 APF will be maintained at £200 billion
3/4 4/8 5/6 6/10 7/8 8/5 9/9 10/7 11/4 12/9 12:00 MPC meeting
2011 1/13 2/10 3/10 4/7 5/5 6/9 7/7 8/4 9/8 12:00 MPC meeting
10/6 12:00 APF extended to £275 billion
11/10 12/8 12:00 MPC meeting
2012 1/12 12:00 MPC meeting
2/9 12:00 APF extended to £325 billion,
3/8 4/5 5/10 6/7 12:00 MPC meeting
7/5 12:00 APF extended to £375 billion
8/2 9/6 10/4 11/8 12/6 12:00 MPC meeting
2013 1/10 2/7 3/7 4/4 12:00 MPC meeting
5/9 12:00 MPC meeting
Notes: Entries in bold denote the announcements that we treat as APF announcements; all other
announcements are treated as non-APF.
40
Table 3: Dates and Times of ECB Monetary Policy Announcements
Year Day Time Description
(Frankfurt)
2007 8/2 13:45 GC meeting
8/9 12:32 Special fine-tuning operations
8/22 15:33 Supplementary LTRO (announcement)
8/23 11:18 Supplementary LTRO (allotment)
9/6 10/4 11/8 12/6 13:45 GC meeting
2008 1/10 2/7 3/6 13:45 GC meeting
3/28 15:00 ECB introduces 6-m LTROs
4/10 5/8 6/5 13:45 GC meeting
7/3 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate increased to 4.25%
8/7 9/4 13:45 GC meeting
10/8 13:00 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased to 3.75%
10/8 Fixed-rate full allotment (FRFA) on MROs
11/6 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased to 3.25%
12/4 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased to 2.50%
2009 1/15 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased to 2.00%
2/5 13:45 GC meeting
3/5 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased to 1.50%
4/2 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased to 1.25%
5/7 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, three 1yr LTROs, CBPP
6/4* 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, CBPP details announced
7/2 8/6 9/3 10/8 11/5 13:45 GC meeting
12/3 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, Phasing out of 6m LTROs, indexation of 1y LTROs
2010 1/14 13:45 GC meeting
2/4 13:45 GC meeting
3/4 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, Phasing out of 3m LTROs, indexation of 6m LTROs
4/8 5/6 13:45 GC meeting
5/9* Securities Market Programme (SMP)
6/10 7/8 13:45 GC meeting
7/28 13:45 Collateral rules tightened, revised haircuts
8/5 9/2 10/7 11/4 12/2 13:45 GC meeting
2011 1/13 2/3 13:45 GC meeting
3/3 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, FRFA extended to July 2011
4/7 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate increased to 1.25%
5/5 6/9 13:45 GC meeting
7/7 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate increased to 1.50%
8/4* 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, SMP covers Spain and Italy
8/7* SMP on Italy and Spain acknowledged by ECB
9/8 13:45 GC meeting
10/6* 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, CBPP2 launched
11/3 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased 1.25%
12/8 13:45-14:30 GC meeting: Two 3-year LTROs, reserve ratio to 1%, MRO rate to 1%
12/21 11:15 Results of first 3-year LTRO
2012 1/12 13:45 GC meeting
2/9 13:45 GC meeting, ECB approved criteria for credit claims for 7 NCBs
2/28 11:16 Results of second 3-year LTRO
3/8 4/4 5/3 6/6 13:45 GC meeting
7/5 13:45 GC meeting, MRO rate decreased to 0.75%, deposit facility rate to 0
7/26* 11:30-12:15 “Whatever it takes” London speech
8/2* 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) program
9/6* 13:45-14:30 GC meeting, OMT details released, no ex-ante size limit
Collateral rules eased
10/4 11/8 12/6 13:45 GC meeting
2013 1/10 2/7 3/7 13:45 GC meeting
3/22 15:00 Collateral rule changes for some uncovered gov-guaranteed bank bonds
4/4 13:45 GC meeting
5/2 13:45 GC meeting: MRO rate to 0.5%, FRFA extended to July 2014
6/6 13:45 GC Meeting
Notes: Entries in bold and bold with * denote announcements that we treat as LTRO-type and
bond purchases announcements, respectively. 14:30 is the start of the ECB press conference. The
announcements on 5/9/2010 and 8/7/2011 are both on Sundays, when financial markets were closed.
We take changes from market close to market open before/after the weekend for these dates.
41
Table 4: Dates and Times of Japanese Monetary Policy Announcements
Year Day Time Description
(Tokyo)
2000 1/17(15:50) 2/10(16:15) 2/24(13:20) 3/8 (15:50) Monetary policy meeting
3/24(13:25) 4/10(15:45) 4/27(13:35) 5/17(15:40) Monetary policy meeting
6/12(16:00) 6/28(13:10) 7/17(16:15) 8/11(17:30) 9/14(14:50) Monetary policy meeting
10/13(15:45) 10/30(14:40) 11/17(14:55) 11/30(12:40) 12/15(14:45) Monetary policy meeting
2001 1/19(16:20) 2/9(17:25) Monetary policy meeting
2/28(16:00) Call rate lowered to 0.15%
3/19(17:40) CAB increased to U5 tr
4/13(12:30) 4/25(13:00) 5/18(12:30) 6/15(12:25) Monetary policy meeting
6/28(12:55) 7/13(13:10) Monetary policy meeting
8/14(13:15) CAB increased to U6 tr
9/18(19:00) Call rate lowered to 0.1%
10/12(13:15) 10/29(14:10) 11/16(12:45) 11/29(12:35) Monetary policy meeting
12/19(15:05) CAB increased to U10-15 tr
2002 1/16(12:50) 2/8(12:30) Monetary policy meeting
2/28(14:05) increase LT bond purchases
3/20(13:35) 4/11(12:25) 4/30(13:10) 5/21(13:10) 6/12(12:25) Monetary policy meeting
6/26(12:55) 7/16(12:30) 8/9(12:50) 9/18(13:20) 10/11(13:00) Monetary policy meeting
10/30(14:45) CAB increased to U15-20 tr
11/19(13:05) 12/17(13:25) Monetary policy meeting
2003 1/22(12:35) 2/14(13:25) 3/5(12:45) Monetary policy meeting
3/25(11:55) CAB increased to U17-22 tr
4/8(13:30) Monetary policy meeting
4/30(13:40) 5/20(13:10) CAB increased to U22-27 and 27-30 tr
6/11(13:20) Monetary policy meeting
6/25(12:05) BoJ starts buying ABS
7/15(11:30) 8/8(11:50) 9/12(13:35) 10/10(14:05) Monetary policy meeting
10/31(12:25) 11/21(12:20) 12/16(11:30) Monetary policy meeting
2004 1/20(12:50) CAB increased to U30-35 tr
2/5(12:05) 2/26(12:10) 3/16(12:00) 4/9(12:45) Monetary policy meeting
4/28(13:05) 5/20(12:10) 6/15(11:40) 6/25(11:30) Monetary policy meeting
7/13( 12:30) 8/10(11:50) 9/9(11:40) 10/13(12:10) Monetary policy meeting
10/29(13:15) 11/18(12:10) 12/17(12:45) Monetary policy meeting
2005 1/19(12:40) 2/17(12:10) 3/16(12:50) 4/6(13:15) Monetary policy meeting
4/28(13:15) 5/20(12:55) 6/15(13:10) 7/13(13:00) Monetary policy meeting
7/27(11:45) 8/9(11:55) 9/8(12:40) 10/12(12:30) Monetary policy meeting
10/31(13:00) 11/18(12:55) 12/16(12:40) 12/27(10:00) Monetary policy meeting
2006 1/20(13:00) 2/9(12:25) 3/3(6:20) Monetary policy meeting
3/9(14:20) QEP ended
4/11(12:55) 4/28(12:50) 5/19(12:15) 6/15(12:20) Monetary policy meeting
7/14(13:40) Call rate increased to 0.25%
8/11(12:20) 9/8(12:40) 10/13(12:50) Monetary policy meeting
10/31(12:50) 11/16(12:25) 12/19(12:30) Monetary policy meeting
2007 1/18 13:05 Monetary policy meeting
2/21 14:19 Call rate increased to 0.5%
3/20(12:40) 4/10(12:48) 4/27(14:07) 5/17(12:41) Monetary policy meeting
6/15(12:18) 7/12(12:55) 8/23(12:35) 9/19(13:21) Monetary policy meeting
10/11(13:32) 10/31(12:42) 11/13 (12:29) 12/20(12:51) Monetary policy meeting
Table continued on next page.
42
Table 4 (continued)
Year Day Time Description
(Tokyo)
2008 1/22(12:19) 2/15(12:51) 3/7(12:52) 4/9(12:24) 4/30(13:28) Monetary policy meeting
5/20(12:04) 6/13(12:23) 7/15(13:34) 8/19(12:30) Monetary policy meeting
9/17(12:47) 10/7(12:58) 10/8(21:00) 10/14(21:38) Monetary policy meeting
10/31 13:58 Call rate lowered to 0.3%
11/21(12:34) 12/2(14:34) Monetary policy meeting
12/19 14:05 Call rate lowered to 0.1%
2009 1/22 13:43 Outright purchases (CPs, corp bonds)
2/19 13:52 Details on corporate bond purchases
3/18(12:27) 4/7(12:22) 4/30(13:37) 5/22(12:33) Monetary policy meeting
6/16(12:34 7/15(13:35) 8/11(11:51) 9/17(12:39) Monetary policy meeting
10/14(13:14) 10/30(13:05) 11/20(12:35) 12/1(15:38) 12/18(12:13) Monetary policy meeting
2010 1/26(12:26) 2/18(11:45) 3/17(12:49) 4/7(12:03) Monetary policy meeting
4/30(13:18) 5/10(12:11) Monetary policy meeting
5/21(12:42) 6/15(12:56) Call rate unchanged, Fund-Provisioning
7/15(12:45) 8/10(12:28) Monetary policy meeting
8/30 (12:11) Enhancement of easy monetary conditions
9/7 12:39 Monetary Policy Meeting
10/5 13:38 APP - U35 trillion
10/28 13:31 APP details
11/5(11:36) 12/21(12:55) Monetary policy meeting
2011 1/25(12:29) 2/15(12:37) 12:29 Monetary Policy meeting
3/14 14:48 APP extended to U40 tr
4/7(13:10) 4/28(13:31)
5/20(12:14) 6/14(12:42) 7/12(13:20) Monetary Policy meeting
8/4 14:00 APP extended to U50 tr
9/7(12:21) 10/7(12:37) 12:21 Monetary Policy meeting
10/27 13:31 APP extended to U55 tr
11/16(12:49) 11/30(22:00) 12/21(12:16) 12:49 Monetary Policy meeting
2012 1/24 12:31 Monetary Policy meeting
2/14 12:43 APP extended to U65 tr
3/13(14:07) 4/10(12:09) Monetary Policy meeting
4/27 12:46 APP extended to U70 tr
5/23(11:37) 6/15(11:52) Monetary Policy meeting
7/12 12:51 No increase in APP, shift in composition
8/9 12:19 Monetary Policy meeting
9/19 12:44 APP extended to U80 trillion
10/5 12:14 Monetary Policy meeting
10/30 14:46 APP extended to U91 tr
11/20 12:14 Monetary Policy meeting
12/20 13:01 APP extended to U101 tr
2013 1/22 12:47 APP extended to U13 tr monthly
2% inflation target, open-ended QE
2/14(12:39) 3/7(12:24) Monetary Policy meeting
4/4 13:40 Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing
4/26(13:35) 5/22(12:07) 6/11(11:48) Monetary Policy meeting
Notes: Entries in bold denote the announcements that we treat as APP announcements; all other
announcements are treated as non-APP.
43
Table 5: Asset Prices Considered
Category US UK EU Japan
Intradaily Data
Bond Futures Two-year Treasury Long Gilt 10-year JGB
Five-year Treasury
Ten-year Treasury
Thirty-year Treasury
Stock Futures S&P FTSE DAX Nikkei
Currency Futures Sterling futures Euro futures Yen futures
10 Year Bond Yields Germany
Italy
Daily Data
Corporate: Higher Grade AAA Moodys 5 year AA AA 5 year A Ind.
Corporate: Lower Grade BAA Moodys 5 year BBB BBB 5 year BBB Fin.
Interest Rate Imp Vol MOVE Index
Sovereign 10 year Spain
France
Notes: All corporate bond yields and the euro area sovereign bond yields are taken from Bloomberg.
44
Table 6: Effects of Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns: Narrow Window
Fed BOE ECB BOJ
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury -0.11
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.01
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.03 (0.04)
Five-year Treasury -0.22
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.00 (0.00) -0.08 (0.05)
Ten-year Treasury -0.25 -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.01 (0.00) -0.04 (0.03)
30-year Treasury -0.16
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.00 (0.00) -0.02 (0.02)
UK Gilt -0.12
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.25 0.02
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.03 (0.02)
Italian 10 Year -0.04
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.02
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.20
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.01 (0.03)
German 10 Year -0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.05
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.05
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.01 (0.02)
Ten-year JGB -0.05
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.01 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01) -0.25
GBP 0.66
∗∗∗
(0.07) -0.82
∗∗∗
(0.12) 0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.13 (0.20)
EUR 0.86
∗∗∗
(0.11) -0.02 (0.07) 0.28
∗∗∗
(0.05) -0.28 (0.24)
JPY 1.21
∗∗∗
(0.09) 0.10
∗∗
(0.05) 0.09
∗∗
(0.04) -0.94
∗∗∗
(0.32)
Stock Returns 0.86
∗∗∗
(0.15) 0.23
(0.12) 0.92
∗∗∗
(0.06) -0.18 (0.83)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.06
∗∗
(0.03)
Corp: Lower Grade -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.13
∗∗∗
(0.04) 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.06 (0.04)
MOVE Index -0.02 (0.03)
Spanish 10 Year -0.37
∗∗∗
(0.04)
French 10 Year 0.01 (0.02)
Notes: Rows labeled Treasury, Gilt and JGB denote the yield changes from futures. Italian, German, French and Spanish yield changes are
from the cash market. Stock returns are S&P, FTSE, DAX and Nikkei futures for the US, UK, euro area and Japan, respectively. Exchange
rate returns are the value of futures contracts on the currency in question, relative to the US dollar, and measured as US dollars per unit of
foreign currency. The higher and lower grade corporate bond yields refer to Moody’s AAA and BAA for the US, the five-year AA and BBB
Bloomberg indices for the euro area and UK, and the five-year industrial A and financial BBB Bloomberg indices for Japan, respectively.
All returns and yield changes are measured in percentage points (100 times log price changes for stock and exchange rate returns). Each
of the returns or yield changes is regressed on the monetary policy surprises for each of the four countries, on announcement days. The
monetary policy surprises and intradaily returns/yield changes are computed as described in the text using the narrow window. Parameters
are estimated by robust regression. Standard errors are in parentheses. One, two and three asterisks denote significance at the 10, 5 and 1
percent significance levels, respectively. Monetary policy surprises are scaled to represent 25 basis point reductions in the ten-year Treasury
yield, the gilt yield, the Italian-German bond spread, and the JGB yield for the US, UK, euro area and Japan, respectively. Consequently,
no standard error is provided for the effect of US, UK or Japanese monetary policy surprises on the ten-year Treasury, gilt or JGB yield
changes, respectively.
45
Table 7: Effects of Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns: Wide Window
Fed BOE ECB BOJ
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury -0.11
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.00 (0.01) 0.03 (0.02)
Five-year Treasury -0.23
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.08
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.03 (0.03)
Ten-year Treasury -0.25 -0.10
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.00 (0.01) -0.02 (0.02)
30-year Treasury -0.17
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.08
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.00 (0.01) -0.02
∗∗
(0.01)
UK Gilt -0.10
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.25 0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.02)
Italian 10 Year -0.07
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.02 (0.01) -0.19
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.02 (0.02)
German 10 Year -0.11
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.07
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.06
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.01 (0.01)
Ten-year JGB -0.05
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.02
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.01
∗∗
(0.01) -0.25
GBP 1.22
∗∗∗
(0.11) -0.87
∗∗∗
(0.14) 0.27
∗∗∗
(0.06) -0.10 (0.15)
EUR 1.54
∗∗∗
(0.17) -0.42
∗∗
(0.18) 0.58
∗∗∗
(0.10) -0.08 (0.19)
JPY 1.07
∗∗∗
(0.10) 0.30
∗∗
(0.14) 0.04 (0.08) -0.11 (0.33)
Stock Returns 0.72
∗∗
(0.34) -0.55
∗∗
(0.28) 1.55
∗∗∗
(0.12) -1.86
∗∗
(0.80)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.03) -0.16
∗∗∗
(0.03) 0.07
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.08
∗∗∗
(0.02)
Corp: Lower Grade -0.15
∗∗∗
(0.03) -0.17
∗∗∗
(0.03) 0.07
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.09
∗∗∗
(0.02)
MOVE Index -0.12
∗∗∗
(0.02)
Spanish 10 Year -0.24
∗∗∗
(0.02)
French 10 Year 0.01 (0.01)
Notes: Rows labeled Treasury, Gilt and JGB denote the yield changes from futures. Italian, German, French and Spanish yield changes are
from the cash market. Stock returns are S&P, FTSE, DAX and Nikkei futures for the US, UK, euro area and Japan, respectively. Exchange
rate returns are the value of futures contracts on the currency in question, relative to the US dollar, and measured as US dollars per unit of
foreign currency. The higher and lower grade corporate bond yields refer to Moody’s AAA and BAA for the US, the five-year AA and BBB
Bloomberg indices for the euro area and UK, and the five-year industrial A and financial BBB Bloomberg indices for Japan, respectively.
All returns and yield changes are measured in percentage points (100 times log price changes for stock and exchange rate returns). Each
of the returns or yield changes is regressed on the monetary policy surprises for each of the four countries, on announcement days. The
monetary policy surprises and intradaily returns/yield changes are computed as described in the text using the wide window. Parameters
are estimated by robust regression. Standard errors are in parentheses. One, two and three asterisks denote significance at the 10, 5 and 1
percent significance levels, respectively. Monetary policy surprises are scaled to represent 25 basis point reductions in the ten-year Treasury
yield, the gilt yield, the Italian-German bond spread, and the JGB yield for the US, UK, euro area and Japan, respectively. Consequently,
no standard error is provided for the effect of US, UK or Japanese monetary policy surprises on the ten-year Treasury, gilt or JGB yield
changes, respectively.
46
Table 8: Effects of Fed Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns: LSAP and other days
LSAP Other
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury -0.05
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.18
∗∗∗
(0.02)
Five-year Treasury -0.21
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.25
∗∗∗
(0.01)
Ten-year Treasury -0.25
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.25
∗∗∗
(0.00)
30-year Treasury -0.22
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.16
∗∗∗
(0.01)
UK Gilt -0.12
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.13
∗∗∗
(0.02)
Italian 10 Year -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.06
(0.03)
German 10 Year -0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.06
∗∗∗
(0.01)
Ten-year JGB -0.04
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01)
GBP 0.67
∗∗∗
(0.14) 0.72
∗∗∗
(0.13)
EUR 0.85
∗∗∗
(0.18) 0.98
∗∗∗
(0.25)
JPY 0.68
∗∗∗
(0.16) 1.45
∗∗∗
(0.20)
Stock Returns 0.91
∗∗∗
(0.26) 0.27 (0.34)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade -0.15
∗∗∗
(0.05) -0.09 (0.09)
Corp: Lower Grade -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.05) -0.14
(0.08)
MOVE Index -0.01 (0.04) -0.10
(0.06)
Notes: This table reports the same regression as in Table 6 (narrow window) for the Federal Reserve alone, except that the regression is
run separately on days when the predominant monetary policy surprise is an LSAP/other announcement, using the classification provided in
Table 1.
47
Table 9: Effects of BOE Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns: APF and other days
APF Other
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury -0.01
(0.01) -0.02
∗∗∗
(0.01)
Five-year Treasury -0.06
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.00)
Ten-year Treasury -0.06
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01)
30-year Treasury -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.02
∗∗∗
(0.01)
UK Gilt -0.25 -0.25
Italian 10 Year -0.01 (0.02) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01)
German 10 Year -0.04
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.05
∗∗∗
(0.00)
Ten-year JGB -0.02 (0.02) -0.01 (0.02)
GBP -1.49
∗∗∗
(0.24) -0.83
∗∗∗
(0.14)
EUR -0.15 (0.16) 0.00 (0.09)
JPY 0.06 (0.10) 0.13
∗∗
(0.05)
Stock Returns -0.01 (0.20) 0.29 (0.19)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade -0.27
∗∗∗
(0.07) -0.08 (0.08)
Corp: Lower Grade -0.24
∗∗∗
(0.07) -0.08 (0.07)
Notes: This table reports the same regression as in Table 6 (narrow window) for the BOE alone, except that the regression is run separately
on days when the predominant monetary policy surprise is an APF/other announcement using the classification provided in Table 2.
48
Table 10: Effects of ECB Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns:
Bond purchase, LSAP and other days
Bond LTRO Other
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury 0.00 (0.01) 0.15
∗∗∗
(0.02) 0.00 (0.02)
Five-year Treasury -0.01
(0.01) 0.08
∗∗∗
(0.02) 0.00 (0.02)
Ten-year Treasury -0.01 (0.01) 0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.01 (0.03)
30-year Treasury 0.00 (0.01) 0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.00 (0.02)
UK Gilt 0.01 (0.01) 0.07
∗∗∗
(0.02) 0.02 (0.03)
Italian 10 Year -0.20
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.21
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.16
∗∗∗
(0.01)
German 10 Year 0.05
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.04 (0.04) 0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01)
Ten-year JGB 0.00 (0.01) 0.03 (0.05) 0.00 (0.04)
GBP 0.13 (0.08) 0.35
(0.19) 0.41
(0.23)
EUR 0.25 (0.17) 0.68 (0.51) 0.29 (0.26)
JPY 0.02 (0.23) -0.07 (0.81) -0.48
∗∗
(0.24)
Stock Returns 1.67
∗∗∗
(0.51) 2.46
∗∗∗
(0.52) 0.81
∗∗
(0.33)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.02) 0.17
(0.10) 0.06 (0.11)
Corp: Lower Grade 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.03) 0.15
(0.09) 0.08 (0.12)
Spanish 10 Year -0.39
∗∗∗
(0.07) -0.50
∗∗∗
(0.15) 0.15 (0.21)
French 10 Year 0.01 (0.02) 0.29
∗∗
(0.12) 0.11 (0.12)
Notes: This table reports the same regression as in Table 6 (narrow window) for the ECB alone, except that the regression is run separately
on days when the predominant monetary policy surprise is a bond purchase/LTRO/other announcement using the classification provided in
Table 3.
49
Table 11: Effects of BOJ Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns: APP and other days
APP Other
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury -0.08
(0.04) 0.04 (0.04)
Five-year Treasury 0.03
(0.01) -0.08 (0.06)
Ten-year Treasury 0.05
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.04 (0.04)
30-year Treasury 0.06
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.02 (0.02)
UK Gilt -0.14 (0.10) -0.02 (0.02)
Italian 10 Year -0.02 (0.06) 0.01 (0.03)
German 10 Year -0.09 (0.09) -0.01 (0.02)
Ten-year JGB -0.25 -0.25
GBP -0.02 (0.44) -0.14 (0.21)
EUR 0.10
∗∗
(0.57) -0.30 (0.25)
JPY -5.05
∗∗∗
(1.31) -0.67
∗∗
(0.30)
Stock Returns 7.29
∗∗
(2.89) -0.66 (0.84)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade -0.21 (0.14) -0.05
(0.03)
Corp: Lower Grade -0.24
(0.13) -0.02 (0.03)
Notes: This table reports the same regression as in Table 6 (narrow window) for the BOJ alone, except that the regression is run separately
on days when the predominant monetary policy surprise is an APP/other announcement using the classification provided in Table 4.
50
Table 12: Effects of Fed Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns:
Effects of First and Second Principal Components
MP S
1t
MP S
2t
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury -0.07
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.17
∗∗∗
(0.01)
Five-year Treasury -0.18
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.17
∗∗∗
(0.01)
Ten-year Treasury -0.24
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.00 (0.00)
30-year Treasury -0.21
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.19
∗∗∗
(0.00)
UK Gilt -0.12
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.01 (0.02)
Italian 10 Year -0.04
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.00 (0.02)
German 10 Year -0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.02
(0.01)
Ten-year JGB -0.05
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03 (0.02)
GBP 0.67
∗∗∗
(0.08) 0.23 (0.19)
EUR 0.86
∗∗∗
(0.11) 0.35 (0.26)
JPY 1.26
∗∗∗
(0.10) -0.10 (0.23)
Stock Returns 0.83
∗∗∗
(0.16) -0.49 (0.40)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) 0.11 (0.09)
Corp: Lower Grade -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) 0.12 (0.09)
MOVE Index -0.03 (0.03) -0.22
∗∗∗
(0.06)
Notes: This table reports the results from estimating equation (2) when each of the returns or yield changes as listed in the notes to Table 6
is regressed onto the two monetary policy surprises for the Fed, on announcement days. The first monetary policy surprise is scaled to lower
ten-year yields by 25 basis points; the second is scaled to lower two-year yields by the same amount. The monetary policy surprises and
intradaily returns/yield changes are computed using the narrow window.
51
Table 13: Estimates of Asymmetry: Narrow Window
Fed BOE ECB BOJ
Intradaily
Stock Returns β
1
-0.90 (0.82) -0.28 (0.37) 1.40
∗∗∗
(0.13) -0.72 (1.45)
β
2
1.79
∗∗
(0.83) 0.68
(0.39) -0.21 (0.16) 0.81 (1.75)
GBP β
1
0.59
∗∗
(0.26) -0.99
∗∗∗
(0.34) 0.10 (0.07) -0.21 (0.38)
β
2
0.07 (0.27) 0.04 (0.44) 0.05 (0.09) 0.12 (0.45)
EUR β
1
0.67
∗∗
(0.33) 0.00 (0.10) 0.37
∗∗∗
(0.10) -0.73
∗∗∗
(0.26)
β
2
0.20 (0.34) -0.19 (0.18) -0.15 (0.12) 0.68
(0.41)
JPY β
1
1.57
∗∗∗
(0.35) 0.15 (0.10) 0.04 (0.08) -1.24
∗∗
(0.54)
β
2
-0.89
∗∗
(0.36) -0.03 (0.13) -0.11 (0.10) 0.44 (0.68)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade β
1
-0.21
∗∗
(0.08) -0.13
(0.07) 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.03) 0.00 (0.07)
β
2
0.07 (0.09) -0.01 (0.09) 0.01 (0.04) -0.09 (0.08)
Corp: Lower Grade β
1
-0.22
∗∗∗
(0.08) -0.15
∗∗
(0.07) 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.01 (0.08)
β
2
0.09 (0.08) -0.01 (0.09) 0.02 (0.04) -0.07 (0.09)
Notes: This table reports the results from estimating equation (3) for each of the returns or yield changes listed in the notes to Table 6. The
monetary policy surprises and intradaily returns/yield changes are computed using the narrow window.
52
Table 14: Effects of Monetary Policy Surprises on Yields/Returns in crisis and non-crisis times
Fed BOE ECB BOJ
2008/09 Other 2008/09 Other 2008/09 Other 2008/09 Other
Intradaily
Two-year Treasury -0.15
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.10
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.00 (0.01) 0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) 0.00 (0.00) 0.05 (0.05) 0.03 (0.05)
Five-year Treasury -0.21
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.24
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.04
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.08
(0.04) -0.01
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.02 (0.02) -0.11 (0.08)
Ten-year Treasury -0.25
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.25
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.04
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.09
(0.05) -0.01
(0.00) -0.02 (0.01) -0.04 (0.05)
30-year Treasury -0.15
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.17
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.03
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.09
∗∗
(0.04) 0.00 (0.00) -0.01
∗∗
(0.00) -0.02 (0.02)
UK Gilt -0.14
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.13
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.25 -0.25 0.01 (0.04) 0.02
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.02 (0.04) -0.03 (0.03)
Italian 10 Year
-0.08
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.02
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.01 (0.02) -0.19
∗∗∗
(0.03) -0.20
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.01 (0.02) 0.01 (0.05)
German 10 Year -0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.08
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.05
∗∗∗
(0.00) -0.04
∗∗∗
(0.01) 0.06
(0.03) 0.05
∗∗∗
(0.00) 0.02 (0.03) -0.03 (0.02)
Ten-year JGB -0.09
∗∗∗
(0.01) -0.04
(0.02) -0.02 (0.02) 0.00 (0.01) 0.05 (0.14) 0.01 (0.01) -0.25 -0.25
GBP 0.65
∗∗∗
(0.10) 1.10
∗∗∗
(0.19) -0.72
∗∗∗
(0.24) -1.28
∗∗∗
(0.21) -0.28 (0.57) 0.14
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.04 (0.35) -0.18 (0.23)
EUR 0.84
∗∗∗
(0.17) 1.42
∗∗∗
(0.25) -0.05 (0.12) 0.06 (0.14) -0.13 (0.64) 0.43
∗∗∗
(0.05) 0.05 (0.27) -0.44 (0.28)
JPY 0.74
∗∗∗
(0.18) 1.08
∗∗∗
(0.21) 0.12 (0.09) 0.06 (0.10) -0.35 (0.77) 0.10
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.79
(0.41) -1.01
∗∗
(0.44)
Stock Returns 0.91
∗∗∗
(0.30) 0.00 (0.39) 0.34 (0.24) 0.07 (0.21) 0.86 (0.85) 0.95
∗∗∗
(0.06) 0.48 (1.37) -0.49 (0.94)
Daily
Corp: Higher Grade -0.15
∗∗∗
(0.05) -0.11 (0.09) -0.17
∗∗∗
(0.07) -0.04 (0.08) 0.29 (0.26) 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.02) -0.01 (0.25) 0.36
∗∗
(0.15)
Corp: Lower Grade -0.15
∗∗∗
(0.04) -0.10 (0.09) -0.20
∗∗∗
(0.07) 0.02 (0.07) 0.30 (0.27) 0.11
∗∗∗
(0.02) 0.00 (0.22) 0.22
(0.13)
MOVE Index -0.02 (0.05) -0.07 (0.06)
Spanish 10 Year 0.28 (0.30) -0.38
∗∗∗
(0.04)
French 10 Year 0.35 (0.30) 0.01 (0.02)
Notes: This table reports the same regressions as in Table 6 (narrow window), except that the regressions are run separately for days in
2008/2009 and other years.
53
Table 15: Specification Tests
Hypothesis Wald Statistic Bootstrap p-value
United States
Σ
0
= Σ
1
51.1 0.002
Σ
1
Σ
0
= R
1
R
0
1
4.7 0.768
United Kingdom
Σ
0
= Σ
1
25.5 0.052
Σ
1
Σ
0
= R
1
R
0
1
6.6 0.514
Euro Area
Σ
0
= Σ
1
100.6 0.000
Σ
1
Σ
0
= R
1
R
0
1
26.9 0.526
Japan
Σ
0
= Σ
1
4.5 0.887
Σ
1
Σ
0
= R
1
R
0
1
2.3 0.746
Notes: This table reports the results of specification tests of the hypotheses that the
variance-covariance matrix of reduced form errors is the same on announcement and
non-announcement days, and that there is a one-dimensional structural shock that
characterizes the difference between these two sets of days. Bootstrap p-values are
included in both cases. The tests and bootstrap methodology are described in Wright
(2012).
54
Figure 1: Changes in Bond Yields Around Selected Announcements
0 5 10 15 20
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
US: March 18 2009 Announcement
Percent
0 5 10 15 20
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
UK: March 5 2009 Announcement
0 5 10 15 20
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
Japan: April 4 2013 Announcement
Year
Percent
0 5 10 15 20
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
US: June 19 2013 Announcement
Year
Notes: For four significant monetary policy announcements, this figure plots the
change in the zero coupon (blue line) and instantaneous forward (red dashed line)
government bond yield curves in that country at the daily frequency from before to
after the announcement.
55
Figure 2: Federal Reserve Impulse Responses
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
Ten-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
Two-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.25
-0.2
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
AAA
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
BAA
Notes: This figure plots the impulse responses (in days) of a monetary policy surprise
consisting of a 25 basis point easing of the ten-year government bond yields in the US,
identified as described in section 4. The specification is a VAR(1) in two- and ten-
year government bond yields and corporate yields. 90 percent bootstrap confidence
intervals are also shown (dashed lines).
56
Figure 3: BOE Impulse Responses
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.25
-0.2
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
Ten-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
Two-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
AA
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
BBB
Notes: This figure plots the impulse responses (in days) of a monetary policy surprise
consisting of a 25 basis point easing of the ten-year government bond yields in the UK,
identified as described in section 4. The specification is a VAR(1) in two- and ten-
year government bond yields and corporate yields. 90 percent bootstrap confidence
intervals are also shown (dashed lines).
57
Figure 4: ECB Impulse Responses
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
Italy 10-Year Spread
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
Spain 10-Year Spread
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
France 10-Year Spread
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Germany 10-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
AA
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
BBB
Notes: This figure plots the impulse responses (in days) of a monetary policy surprise
consisting of a 25 basis point easing of Italian government bond yields in the euro
area, identified as described in section 4. The specification is a VAR(1) in ten-year
sovereign spreads, ten-year German yields and corporate yields. 90 percent bootstrap
confidence intervals are also shown (dashed lines).
58
Figure 5: BoJ Impulse Responses
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.35
-0.3
-0.25
-0.2
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
Ten-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.2
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
Two-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.25
-0.2
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
0.1
A Industrial
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.5
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
BBB Financial
Notes: This figure plots the impulse responses (in days) of a monetary policy surprise
consisting of a 25 basis point easing of the ten-year government bond yields in Japan,
identified as described in section 4. The specification is a VAR(1) in two- and ten-
year government bond yields and corporate yields. 90 percent bootstrap confidence
intervals are also shown (dashed lines).
59
Figure 6: Federal Reserve Impulse Responses: Identification Through
Heteroskedasticity
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.5
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
Ten-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
Two-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
AAA
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
BAA
Notes: This figure plots the impulse responses (in days) of a monetary policy surprise
consisting of a 25 basis point easing of the ten-year government bond yields in the
US, using identification through heteroskedasiticty as described in section 5. The
specification is a VAR(1) in two- and ten-year government bond yields and corporate
yields. 90 percent bootstrap confidence intervals are also shown (dashed lines).
60
Figure 7: ECB Impulse Responses: Identification Through
Heteroskedasticity
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.5
0
0.5
Italy 10-Year Spread
0 50 100 150 200 250
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
Spain 10-Year Spread
0 50 100 150 200 250
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
France 10-Year Spread
0 50 100 150 200 250
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
Germany 10-Year
0 50 100 150 200 250
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
AA
0 50 100 150 200 250
-2
-1
0
1
BBB
Notes: This figure plots the impulse responses (in days) of a monetary policy surprise
consisting of a 25 basis point easing of Italian government bond yields in the euro area,
identified , using identification through heteroskedasiticty as described in section 5.
The specification is a VAR(1) in ten-year sovereign spreads, ten-year German yields
and corporate yields. 90 percent bootstrap confidence intervals are also shown (dashed
lines).
61
References
Akkaya, Yildiz, “Uncertainty of Interest Rate Path as a Monetary Policy Instru-
ment,” 2014. working paper.
Arai, Natsuki, “The Effect of Monetary Policy Announcements at the Zero Lower
Bound,” 2013. working paper.
Bredin, Don, Stuart Hyde, Dirk Nitzsche, and Gerald O’Reilly, “UK stock
returns and the impact of domestic monetary policy shocks,” Journal of Business
Finance and Accounting, 2007, 34, 872–888.
Cahill, Michael E., Stefania D’Amico, Canlin Li, and John S. Sears, “Du-
ration Risk versus Local Supply Channel in Treasury Yields: Evidence from the
Federal Reserve’s Asset Purchase Announcements,” 2013. Finance and Economics
Discussion Series, 2013-35.
Cenesizoglu, Tolga and Badye O. Essid, “The Effect of Monetary Policy on
Credit Spreads,” Journal of Financial Research, 2012, 35, 581–613.
D’Amico, Stefania and Thomas B. King, “Flow and Stock Effects of Large-Scale
Treasury Purchases,” Journal of Financial Economics, 2013, 108, 425–448.
, William English, David opez-Salido, and Edward Nelson, “The Fed-
eral Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programmes: Rationale and Effects,”
Economic Journal, 2012, 122, 415–446.
Doh, Taeyoung, “The Efficacy of Large-Scale Asset Purchases at the Zero Lower
Bound,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 2010, 2, 5–34.
Duffie, Darrell, “Asset Price Dynamics with Slow-Moving Capital,” Journal of
Finance, 2010, 65, 1238–1268.
Eggertsson, Gauti and Michael Woodford, “The Zero Lower Bound on Interest
Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
2003, 1, 139–211.
Ehrmann, Michael and Marcel Fratzscher, “Equal Size, Equal Role? Interest
Rate Interdependence between the Euro Area and the United States,” Economic
Journal, 2005, 115, 930–950.
Fama, Eugene, Kenneth French, Michael Jensen, and Richard Roll, “The
Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information,” International Economic Review,
1969, 10, 1–21.
Faust, Jon, John H. Rogers, Shing-Yi B. Wang, and Jonathan H. Wright,
“The High-Frequency Response of Exchange Rates and Interest Rates to Macroe-
conomic Announcements,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2007, 54, 1051–1068.
Fratzscher, Marcel, Marco Lo Duca, and Roland Straub, “On the Interna-
tional Spillovers of US Quantitative Easing,” 2013. ECB working paper 1557.
62
Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian Sack, “Large-
Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work?,” International
Journal of Central Banking, 2011, 7, 3–44.
Ghysels, Eric, Julien Idier, Simone Manganelli, and Olivier Vergote, “A
high frequency assessment of the ECB Securities Markets Programme,” 2012. work-
ing paper.
Giannone, Domenico, Michele Lenza, Huw Pill, and Lucrezia Reichlin,
“Non-standard monetary policy measures and monetary developments,” in Jagjit S.
Chadha and Sean Holly, eds., Interest Rates, Prices and Liquidity—Lessons from
the Financial Crisis, Cambridge University Press 2011.
Gilchrist, Simon and Egon Zakrajsek, “The Impact of the Federal Reserve’s
Large-Scale Asset Purchase Program on Corporate Credit Risk,” 2013. NBER
Working Paper 19337.
, David opez-Salido, and Egon Zakrajsek, “Monetary Policy and Real Bor-
rowing Costs at the ZLB,” 2013. working paper.
Glick, Reuven and Sylvain Leduc, “Central Bank Announcements of Asset Pur-
chases and the Impact on Global Financial and Commodity Markets,” Journal of
International Money and Finance, 2012, 31, 2078–2101.
and , “The Effects of Unconventional and Conventional U.S. Monetary Policy on
the Dollar,” 2013. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco working paper 2013-11.
Greenwood, Robin and Dimitri Vayanos, “Bond Supply and Excess Bond Re-
turns,” Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming.
G¨urkaynak, Refet S. and Jonathan H. Wright, “Market-Based Measures of
International Monetary Policy Dependence,” 2011. working paper.
and , “Identification and Inference Using Event Studies,” The Manchester
School, 2013, 81, 48–65.
, Brian Sack, and Eric T. Swanson, “The Sensitivity of Long-Term Interest
Rates to Economic News: Evidence and Implications for Macroeconomic Models,”
American Economic Review, 2005a, 95, 425–436.
, , and , “Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words? The Response of As-
set Prices to Monetary Policy Actions and Statements,” International Journal of
Central Banking, 2005b, 1, 55–93.
Hamilton, James D. and Jing Cynthia Wu, “The Effectiveness of Alternative
Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment,” Journal of Money
Credit and Banking, 2012, 44, 3–46.
Huber, Peter J., Robust Statistics, Hoboken, New Jersey: John Wiley and Sons,
1981.
IMF, “Unconventional Monetary Policies–Recent Experience and Prospects,” 2013.
Background paper.
63
Jeanne, Olivier, “Fiscal Challenges to Monetary Dominance in the Euro Area: A
Theoretical Perspective,” Banque de France Financial Stability Review, 2012, 16,
143–150.
Joyce, Michael A.S., Ana Lasaosa, Ibrahim Stevens, and Matthew Tong,
“The Financial Market Impact of Quantitative Easing in the United Kingdom,”
International Journal of Central Banking, 2011, 7, 113–161.
and Matthew Tong, “QE and the Gilt Market: a Disaggregated Analysis,”
Economic Journal, 2012, 122, 348–384.
Kiley, Michael T., “The Response of Equity Prices to Movements in Long-term
Interest Rates Associated With Monetary Policy Statements: Before and After the
Zero Lower Bound,” 2013a. Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 2013-15.
, “Monetary Policy Statements, Treasury Yields, and Private Yields: Before and
After the Zero Lower Bound,” 2013b. Finance and Economics Discussion Series,
2013-16.
Kilian, Lutz, “Small-sample confidence intervals for impulse response functions,”
Review of Economics and Statistics, 1998, 80, 218–230.
Krishnamurthy, Arvind and Annette Vissing-Jorgenson, “The Effects of
Quantitative Easing on Long-term Interest Rates,” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 2011, 2, 215–265.
and , “The Ins and Outs of LSAPs,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Economic Policy Symposium, 2013.
Kuttner, Kenneth, “Monetary Policy Surprises and Interest Rates: Evidence from
the Fed Funds Futures Market,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2001, 47, 523–
544.
Lenza, Michele, Huw Pill, and Lucrezia Reichlin, “Monetary Policy in Excep-
tional Times,” Economic Policy, 2010, 25, 295–339.
Li, Canlin and Min Wei, “Term Structure Modeling with Supply Factors and the
Federal Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs,” International Journal of
Central Banking, 2013, 9, 3–39.
Lou, Dong, Hongjun Yan, and Jinfan Zhang, “Anticipated and Repeated
Shocks in Liquid Markets,” Review of Financial Studies, 2013, 26, 1891–1912.
Meaning, Jack and Feng Zhu, “The Impact of Recent Central Bank Asset Pur-
chase Programmes,” BIS Quarterly Review, 2011, pp. 73–83.
Mitchell, Mark, Lasse H. Pedersen, and Todd Pulvino, “Slow Moving Capi-
tal,” American Economic Review, 2007, 97, 215–220.
Modigliani, Franco and Richard Sutch, “Innovations in Interest Rate Policy,”
American Economic Review, 1966, 52, 178–197.
64
and , “Debt Management and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: An Em-
pirical Analysis of Recent Experience,” Journal of Political Economy, 1967, 75,
569–589.
Neely, Christopher, “The Large-Scale Asset Purchases Had Large International
Effects,” 2010. Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis working paper 2010-18A.
Piazzesi, Monika and Eric T. Swanson, “Futures Prices as Risk-Adjusted Fore-
casts of Monetary Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2008, 55, 677–691.
Raskin, Matthew, “The Effects of Monetary Policy on Corporate Bond Yields,”
2013. working paper.
Rigobon, Roberto and Brian Sack, “Identification through heteroskedasticity,”
Review of Economics and Statistics, 2003a, 85, 777–792.
and , “Measuring the response of monetary policy to the stock market,” Quar-
terly Journal of Economics, 2003b, 118, 639–669.
and , “The impact of monetary policy on asset prices,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 2004, 51, 1553–1575.
and , “The effects of war risk on US financial markets,” Journal of Banking
and Finance, 2005, 29, 1769–1789.
Rosa, Carlos, “How “Unconventional” Are Large-Scale Asset Purchases? The Im-
pact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices,” 2012. Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Staff Reports, 560.
Stein, Jeremy C., “Evaluating Large-Scale Asset Purchases,” 2012. Speech deliv-
ered at the Brookings Institution, Washington, October 11 2012.
Swanson, Eric T., “Let’s Twist Again: A High-Frequency Event-Study Analysis
of Operation Twist and Its Implications for QE2,” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 2011, 1, 151–188.
Vayanos, Dimitri and Jean-Luc Vila, “A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term
Structure of Interest Rates,” 2009. Working paper.
Williams, John C. and David Reifschneider, “Three Lessons for Monetary
Policy in a Low Inflation Era,” Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 2000, 32,
936–966.
Wright, Jonathan H., “What Does Monetary Policy do at the Zero Lower Bound?,”
Economic Journal, 2012, 122, 447–466.
65